Lade Inhalt...

The Influence of Domestic Interests on ASEAN politics

Help or Hinders to Economic Integration?

©2006 Masterarbeit 161 Seiten

Zusammenfassung

Inhaltsangabe:Abstract:
Until the 1990s, the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) had a long, however unsuccessful tradition of promoting regional economic development through inter-governmental cooperation. This changed in 1992 with the foundation of the ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA), which is regarded as ASEAN’s first serious step towards regional economic integration.
AFTA’s aim is to abolish trade barriers among the participating countries, be it tariffs or non-tariff barriers. The member countries are therefore required to liberalize their economies through adjustments of their domestic tariff systems and through the elimination of non-tariff barriers (NTBs). The formerly high degrees of economic protection have to be gradually reduced and ultimately abolished completely – measures, that the ASEAN member states were long unwilling to implement. Hence, ASEAN’s decision to found AFTA in 1992 was very sceptically perceived by the international community.
Indeed, the development of AFTA displays two contrary characteristics. On the one hand, the ASEAN members decided to accelerate the implementation of AFTA by five years and complemented it with two additional programmes, the ASEAN Investment Area (AIA) and the ASEAN Framework Agreement on Services (AFAS). On the other hand, the institutional design of AFTA provides the member countries with a high degree of flexibility to prolong or delay the process of implementation and re-negotiate commitments already made.
Two conclusions can be drawn from the above stated developments: On the hand, the signing of the AFTA framework in 1992 clearly indicates a major shift in the member states’ attitude towards regional economic integration. Moreover, the initially quick implementation of the original agreement, as well as its acceleration by five years and the inclusion of those potentially contentious issue areas – namely trade in unprocessed agricultural products and in services – which the member countries had excluded from the original AFTA framework, underline this shifting attitude towards regional economic integration. On the other hand, some member states delayed the implementation of tariff reductions and the negotiation of sensitive products, indicating that they were not equally committed to the process of implementation.
These conclusions lead to the two research questions that this thesis answers:
Firstly, why did the Southeast Asian states change their preferences towards regional […]

Leseprobe

Inhaltsverzeichnis


Kathrin Prasse
The Influence of Domestic Interests on ASEAN politics
Help or Hinders to Economic Integration?
ISBN-10: 3-8324-9865-6
ISBN-13: 978-3-8324-9865-8
Druck Diplomica® GmbH, Hamburg, 2006
Zugl. Westfälische Wilhelms-Universität Münster, Münster, Deutschland,
MA-Thesis / Master, 2006
Dieses Werk ist urheberrechtlich geschützt. Die dadurch begründeten Rechte,
insbesondere die der Übersetzung, des Nachdrucks, des Vortrags, der Entnahme von
Abbildungen und Tabellen, der Funksendung, der Mikroverfilmung oder der
Vervielfältigung auf anderen Wegen und der Speicherung in Datenverarbeitungsanlagen,
bleiben, auch bei nur auszugsweiser Verwertung, vorbehalten. Eine Vervielfältigung
dieses Werkes oder von Teilen dieses Werkes ist auch im Einzelfall nur in den Grenzen
der gesetzlichen Bestimmungen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes der Bundesrepublik
Deutschland in der jeweils geltenden Fassung zulässig. Sie ist grundsätzlich
vergütungspflichtig. Zuwiderhandlungen unterliegen den Strafbestimmungen des
Urheberrechtes.
Die Wiedergabe von Gebrauchsnamen, Handelsnamen, Warenbezeichnungen usw. in
diesem Werk berechtigt auch ohne besondere Kennzeichnung nicht zu der Annahme,
dass solche Namen im Sinne der Warenzeichen- und Markenschutz-Gesetzgebung als frei
zu betrachten wären und daher von jedermann benutzt werden dürften.
Die Informationen in diesem Werk wurden mit Sorgfalt erarbeitet. Dennoch können
Fehler nicht vollständig ausgeschlossen werden, und die Diplomarbeiten Agentur, die
Autoren oder Übersetzer übernehmen keine juristische Verantwortung oder irgendeine
Haftung für evtl. verbliebene fehlerhafte Angaben und deren Folgen.
© Diplomica GmbH
http://www.diplom.de, Hamburg 2006
Printed in Germany

Autorenprofil
Kathrin Prasse
.
M.A. Southeast Asian Studies
Westfalenstr. 90
48165 Münster
Tel.: 02501-928759
Email: Kathrin.Prasse@web.de
meine persönlichen Daten
geboren am 14.02.1980 in Dortmund,
ledig, ortsungebunden
meine wichtigsten Eigenschaften
Einsatzbereitschaft, Teamfähigkeit, Verantwortungsbewusstsein,
Aufgeschlossenheit, Organisationstalent, Flexibilität
mein angestrebter Tätigkeitsbereich
Politische Beratung mit Südostasienschwerpunkt,
Entwicklungszusammenarbeit
Studium
26.06.2006
Masterprüfung
Akad. Grad:
Master of Arts of Southeast Asian Studies
(Abschlussnote: 1,29)
Masterarbeit: The Influence of Domestic Interests on ASEAN
Politics - Help or Hinders to Economic Integration?
2004 - 2006
Masterstudium Südostasienwis-
senschaften an der Westfälische Hauptfach:
Politikwissenschaften
Wilhelms-Universität Münster
Nebenfächer: Soziologie, Ethnologie
2002 - 2008
Magisterstudium Politikwissen-
schaften an der Westfälische
Hauptfach:
Politikwissenschaften (Fokus: Entwicklungspolitik)
Wilhelms-Universität Münster
Nebenfächer: Volkswirtschaftslehre, Ethnologie
Beruflicher Werdegang
Frühjahr 2004
Ferme du Chevres, Lisieux
Zweimonatiges Berufspraktikum in Frankreich
Sommer 2002
Greenways Thailand, HadYai
Dreimonatiger freiwilliger, sozialer Dienst in thailändischer NGO
2002 - 2003
Westfälische Hypothekenbank,
Projektmitarbeiterin in den Bereichen Schuldschein- und
Dortmund
Wertpapierverwaltung, Securitization and Structured Finance
1991 - 2002
Berufsausbildung zur
Ausbildungsbeginn im August 1999
Bankkauffrau, Dortmund
Abschlussprüfung im Januar 2002 (Abschlussnote 2,0)
Sprachen
16 Jahre
Englisch
verhandlungssicher
3 Jahre
Wirtschaftsenglisch
KMK-Foreign language certificate, niveau III (vantage)
5 Jahre
Latein
Großes Latinum
3 Jahre
Thai
Fortgeschrittenenkurs III (einfache Verständigung in Wort u. Schrift)
2 Jahre
Italienisch
einfache Verständigung, Teilnahme an Schüleraustauschen
2 Jahre
Französisch
einfache Verständigung, Praktikumserfahrung
weitere Kenntnisse
PC-Kenntnisse
Sehr sicherer Umgang mit MS Office, Kenntnisse in LaTEX
Führerschein
Pkw, Klasse 3

ii
"I have, of course, no crystal ball, only an approach that says: pay attention to
politicians and other public individuals acting in context. Assess the environment,
both domestic and international, from which they draw resources. Observe closely
how they accumulate, mobilize, and deploy those resources, and how others react to
them." (Liddle: 1996; Quoted in Case: 2002: p. 32).

iii
Table of Contents
List of Tables...
page
v
List of Charts... v
List of Figures... v
List of Appendixes... v
List of Abbreviations... vi
1. Introduction... 1
1.1. Background to and significance of this research... 2
1.2. Research design and existing literature... 4
1.3. Scope and applicability of research... 7
1.4. Research method... 10
1.5. Content outline... 11
2. Theoretical Framework... 13
2.1. Regional economic integration in theory... 13
2.2. Interests, coalitions, and political influence in theory... 15
2.2.1. Economic interests and coalition-forming... 15
2.2.1.1. The internationalist coalition... 17
2.2.1.2. The nationalist coalition... 18
2.2.2. Political institutions, political influence and state capacity... 19
2.2.3. The independent and the intervening variables... 20
2.2.4. The dependent and its operational variable... 22
2.3. Conclusion ...
23
3. Economic development and regional economic integration... 25
3.1. Overview: patronage and early economic development ... 25
3.1.1. Indonesia... 29
3.1.2. Malaysia... 30
3.1.3. Thailand... 31
3.1.4. Summary... 32
3.2. From regional economic cooperation to integration... 33
3.2.1. Early economic cooperation: the PTA... 33
3.2.2. Transition towards regional economic integration... 34
3.2.3. Regional economic integration through AFTA... 35
3.3. Summary and conclusion... 39
4. Interests, coalitions, political influence and policy outcome...
...
41
4.1. The role of FDI: changing investment patterns... 42
4.2. Country-specific analysis: The ASEAN Three... 49
4.2.1. Indonesia... 49
4.2.1.1. Economic policy-making and state capacity... 50
4.2.1.2. Relevant actors: economic interests and political influence... 51
4.2.1.2.1. The role of the president... 52
4.2.1.2.2. The role of the bureaucracy... 52
4.2.1.2.3. The role of the business actors... 54

iv
4.2.1.3. AFTA's pre-founding phase: coalition-forming and
economic policy outcome from 1985 to 1990...
61
4.2.1.4. AFTA's implementation phase: coalition-forming and
economic policy outcome from 1991 to 1995...
64
4.2.1.5. Preliminary conclusion... 69
4.2.2. Malaysia... 70
4.2.2.1. Economic policy-making and state capacity... 71
4.2.2.2. Relevant actors: economic interests and political influence... 72
4.2.2.2.1. The role of the prime minister... 73
4.2.2.2.2. The role of the bureaucracy... 74
4.2.2.2.3. The role of the business actors... 76
4.2.2.3. AFTA's pre-founding phase: Coalition-forming and
economic policy outcome from 1985 to 1990...
82
4.2.2.4. AFTA's implementation phase: coalition-forming and
economic policy outcome from 1991 to 1995...
84
4.2.2.5. Preliminary conclusion... 87
4.2.3. Thailand... 87
4.2.3.1. Economic policy-making and state capacity... 88
4.2.3.2. Relevant actors: economic interests and political influence... 90
4.2.3.2.1. The role of the bureaucracy... 90
4.2.3.2.2. The role of the business actors... 92
4.2.3.2.3. The role of the governments... 96
4.2.3.3. AFTA's pre-founding phase: Coalition-forming and
economic policy outcome from 1985 to 1991...
101
4.2.3.4. AFTA's founding phase: Coalition-forming and economic
policy outcome from 1991 to 1992...
103
4.2.3.5. AFTA's implementation phase: Coalition-forming and
economic policy outcome from 1992 to 1995...
106
4.2.3.6. Preliminary conclusion... 108
4.3. Summary and conclusion: the influence of domestic interests on the
foundation and implementation of AFTA...
111
5. Assessment and final conclusion... 116
5.1. Summary of analysis... 116
5.2. Assessment of the theoretical framework... 124
5.3. Final conclusion... 127
6. Bibliography... 128
7. Appendix... 136
8. Declaration... 151

v
Tables, Charts, Figures, and Appendixes
List of Tables
Table 2.1
Interests, coalition-forming and political influence in theory... 18
Table 3.1
Summary: the CEPT Acceleration for ASEAN-6...
38
Table 4.1
Economic interest and political influence of foreign investors... 46
Table 4.2.1
Actors' interests, coalition-forming and political influence... 60
Table 4.2.2.
Actors' interests, coalition-forming and political influence... 82
Table 4.2.3.
Actors' interests, coalition-forming and political influence... 100
List of Charts
Chart 4.1
Growth of GDP of the ASEAN Three economies from 1985 to
1997...
47
Chart 4.2
Flow of world-FDI to ASEAN-10 and China from 1985 to
1997...
48
List of Figures
Figure 2.1
Economic segmentation under free trade conditions... 13
Figure 2.2
Economic segmentation under protectionist conditions... 14
Figure 2.3
Coalitional influence on political decision-making and the
policy choice...
23
Figure 2.4
Political influence and the economic policy choice... 24
Figure 3.1
Political patronage and economic growth... 27
Figure 3.2
Economic segmentation under early AFTA conditions... 38
List of Appendixes
Appendix 1.1 Growth of GDP of the ASEAN Three economies from 1985 to
1997...
136
Appendix 1.2 Flow of world-FDI to ASEAN-10 and China from 1985 to
1997...
136
Appendix 2
The Indonesian business elite, their political connection and
their economic treatment...
137
Appendix 3
The Malaysian business elite, their political connection and
their economic treatment...
141
Appendix 4
The Thai business elite, their political connection and their
economic treatment...
146

vi
List of Abbreviations
AEM
ASEAN Economic Ministers
AEMM
ASEAN Economic Ministers Meeting
AFAS
ASEAN Framework Agreement on Services
AFTA
ASEAN Free Trade Area
AIA
ASEAN Investment Area
AIC
ASEAN Industrial Complementation Scheme
AIJV
ASEAN Industrial Joint Venture Scheme
AIP
ASEAN Industrial Projects Scheme
AMM
ASEAN Ministerial Meeting
ASEAN
Association of Southeast Asian Nations
ASEAN Three Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand
ASEAN-5
the founding members of ASEAN, i.e. ASEAN Three plus Singapore
and the Philippines
ATI
Association of Thai Industries
BBC
the Brand-to-Brand Scheme
BOI
Board of Investment
Bulog
Badan Urusan Logistik
CAFTA
China-ASEAN Free Trade Area
CBU Completely
build
up
CEPT Scheme Common Effective Preferential Tariffs Scheme
CKD Completely
knocked
down
EAEC
East Asian Economic Caucus
EPU
Economic Planning Unit
FT Fast
Track
GEL
General Exception List
HICOM
Heavy Industries Corporation of Malaysia
hSL
highly Sensitive List
INL Inclusion
List
JPPCC
Private Sector Consultative Committee
MCA
Malaysian Chinese Association
MIC
Malaysian Indian Congress
MIDA
Malaysian Industrial Development Authority
MITI
Ministry of International Trade and Industry (Malaysia)
MNE Mulinational
enterprise
MoF
Ministry of Finance
MTUC
Malaysian Trades Union Congress
NDP
New Development Policy
NEP
New Economic Policy
(continued on next page)

vii
NESDB
National Economic and Social Development Board
NIC
Newly Industrializing Country
NT Normal
Track
NTB non-tariff
barrier
PTA Preferential
Trade
Arrangement
QR quantitative
and
qualitative restrictions
SL
Sensitive List
SME
small and medium enterprises
TEL
Temporary Exclusion List
TNE Transnational
enterprise
UMNO
United Malays National Organization
VAT Value-added
tax

1
1. Introduction
Until the 1990s, the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) had a
long, however unsuccessful tradition of promoting regional economic development
through inter-governmental cooperation.
1
This changed in 1992 with the foundation
of the ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA), which is regarded as ASEAN's first serious
step towards regional economic integration.
2
AFTA's aim is to abolish trade barriers among the participating countries, be
it tariffs or non-tariff barriers. The member countries are therefore required to
liberalize their economies through adjustments of their domestic tariff systems and
through the elimination of non-tariff barriers (NTBs). The formerly high degrees of
economic protection have to be gradually reduced and ultimately abolished
completely ­ measures, that the ASEAN member states were long unwilling to
implement. Hence, ASEAN's decision to found AFTA in 1992 was very sceptically
perceived by the international community.
3
Indeed, the development of AFTA displays two contrary characteristics. On
the one hand, the ASEAN members decided to accelerate the implementation of
AFTA by five years and complemented it with two additional programmes, the
ASEAN Investment Area (AIA) and the ASEAN Framework Agreement on Services
(AFAS).
4
On the other hand, the institutional design of AFTA provides the member
countries with a high degree of flexibility to prolong or delay the process of
implementation and re-negotiate commitments already made.
5
Two conclusions can be drawn from the above stated developments: On the
hand, the signing of the AFTA framework in 1992 clearly indicates a major shift in
the member states' attitude towards regional economic integration. Moreover, the
initially quick implementation of the original agreement, as well as its acceleration
by five years and the inclusion of those potentially contentious issue areas ­ namely
trade in unprocessed agricultural products and in services ­ which the member
countries had excluded from the original AFTA framework, underline this shifting
attitude towards regional economic integration. On the other hand, some member
states delayed the implementation of tariff reductions and the negotiation of sensitive
1
Cf. Lim: 2004: pp. 200-204.
2
Hund: 2003: 139. The difference between economic cooperation and economic integration are
explained in Chapter 2.1.
3
Cf. Nadal de Simone: 1996: pp. 113-116; Tan: 1996: pp. 162-169.
4
The AFTA and the AFTA Plus programmes are dealt with at greater length in Chapter 3.2.
5
Cf. Nesadurai: 2003: p. 29.

2
products, indicating that they were not equally committed to the process of
implementation.
These conclusions lead to the two research questions that this thesis answers:
Firstly, why did the Southeast Asian states change their preferences towards
regional economic integration and founded AFTA? Secondly, why was AFTA
institutionalized in a way, that allowed frequent delays and re-negotiations of its
implementation?
To answer these questions, the argumentation of this thesis is grounded on a
basic assumption: The foundation and implementation of AFTA was, to a large
extent, determined by the economic interests of politically dominant domestic
actors.
6
This is not to say, that political decision-making is solely dictated by the
demands of powerful domestic constituencies. Nevertheless, important is, that the
degree of domestic support, which politicians enjoy and on which their domestic
political legitimacy is grounded, depends on the extent to which they are able to
satisfy the domestic demands.
7
To understand the assumption, which underlies the analytical part of this
thesis, it is crucial to consider, that, for reasons outlined in Chapter 2.1, regional
economic integration through trade liberalization diametrically affects the business
interests of different domestic actors. This is even more true for the Southeast Asian
countries, which had long been adopting a distributive and protective approach
towards economic development. This approach can no longer hold under conditions
of trade liberalization. Tensions between economic growth and domestic distribution,
that policymakers are confronted with, are likely to shape their preferences towards
regional economic integration.
8
Simply put, trade liberalization will create `winners
and losers'. Domestic power struggles for, or against, regional economic integration
are likely to occur.
1.1. Background to and significance of this research
According to Moravcsik, societal interests and institutions have a
fundamental impact on state behaviour in world politics, by shaping state
6
Cf. Moravcsik: 1997: p. 1.
7
Cf. Nesadurai: 2002: p. 6.
8
Ibid.

3
preferences.
9
Hence, "domestic politics do matter"
10
to regional economic
integration. While abundant literature deals with Southeast Asian regional economic
integration from mere outside-in perspectives
11
, inside-out approaches, which try to
identify domestic incentives for or against integration, however, are according to
Rüland and Jayasuriya, rare and seldom applied to explain the ASEAN members'
changing state preferences towards regional economic integration.
12
The existence of this gap in the literature on ASEAN regional economic
integration is peculiar for, at least, three reasons: First of all, since the theories of
international relations overcame the predominance of realist assumptions, a variety
of scientifically acknowledged theoretical approaches has emerged, appropriate for
analysing the influence of underlying domestic pressures on intra-regional
cooperation.
13
Among the most prominent certainly is Putnam's very influential
essay "Two-level games".
14
Secondly, a good deal of research on the political economy of the Southeast
Asian tiger states has already been conducted. The more than two hundred pages
thick World Bank report ­ The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public
Policy ­ of 1993, which analyses domestic economic policies as the main cause of
the Asian miracle of the early to mid-1990s, has especially inspired an immeasurable
amount of literature on the Southeast Asian economic development. Yet, this
literature does usually not lay much emphasis on the examination of domestic
influences on the foundation and implementation of AFTA.
9
Cf. Moravcsik: 1997: p. 1.
10
Milner, Helen: 1997: p. 3.
11
The so-called outside-in approaches are based on the arguments of institutionalism, constructivism,
or realism.
12
Cf. Jayasuriya: 2001: p. 2; Rüland: 2002: p. 5.
13
Cf. Putnam: 1988: p. 427-451: Early works on the role of domestic actors in influencing state
politics stem from Karl Deutsch and Ernst Haas. Structuralist approaches, such as those conducted by
Graham Allison, Peter Katzenstein and Stephen Krasner, focus on state capacity and examine political
institutions through which domestic interests are aggregated, represented, and reflected in foreign
policy choices. Independently, these authors conclude that political decision-makers are highly
concerned with both domestic and international pressures.
Putnam perceives international bargaining
as a two-level game in which domestic politics and international relations have reciprocal influences.
Hence, the analysis of two-level games requires a decomposition of the bargaining process into two
distinctive stages ­ the domestic and the international level. Domestic interests and actors are crucial
for determining the outcome of international bargaining.
14
Ibid.: Putnam perceives international bargaining as a two-level game in which domestic politics and
international relations have reciprocal influences. Hence, the analysis of two-level games requires a
decomposition of the bargaining process into two distinctive stages ­ the domestic and the
international level. Domestic interests and actors are crucial for determining the outcome of
international bargaining.

4
Thirdly, basically neo-liberal institutionalist or constructivist approaches have
been applied to ASEAN regional economic integration.
15
Here, research is focused
on institution-building
16
and underlying common identities
17
. When applying these
approaches to the framework of AFTA, institutional deficiencies are frequently
identified as the major obstacles to regional economic integration.
18
Despite this,
regional economic integration among the ASEAN member states does happen.
Hence, these approaches, which are not applicable when considering the interests of
economic actors as a possible explanatory framework for changing state preferences,
seem not to be able to explain regional economic integration among the ASEAN
member states.
19
The key concern of this paper is therefore to provide an alternative
explanation by opening the black box of international politics and draw the reader's
attention to the domestic interests underpinning and shaping state preferences
towards regional economic integration, here represented by AFTA. According to the
literature, which was available to conduct this research, a systematic analysis
focusing on the influence of domestic interests on ASEAN regional economic
integration has not been undertaken prior to this attempt. This thesis therefore
contributes important insights into the domestic politics of the ASEAN member
states with regard to regional economic integration to the existing literature.
1.2. Research
design
and existing literature
In Southeast Asia, as in contrast to Europe, domestic interests cannot
influence the regional level directly. Instead, domestic actors are required to exert
15
Cf. Hund: 2003; Rüland: 2002: p. 5.
16
Cf. Rüland: 2002: p. 7: Institutionalization is the process of establishing a common overarching
infrastructure which serves to coordinate meetings such as a secretariat. Regionalism identifies two
different types of institutionalization: hard institution-building based on rules-based mechanisms and
high governance costs, while soft institutionalization creates shallow dialogue and cooperative fora, in
which the nation-state prevails the dominant actor and in which governance costs are low due to the
lack of common institutions.
17
Cf. Hund 2003: pp. 29-30; Rüland: 2002: p. 8: Constructivists argue that regionalism stimulates
collective identity-building by shaping "differences between self and other" and contributing to the
cohesion of a group.
18
In this regard, constructivists argue that theses institutional weaknesses originate from ASEAN's
collective norms, which do not seem to be capable of effectively promoting deeper regional economic
integration. Cf. Hund 2003: pp. 29-30; 136: ASEAN`s traditional collective norms are: absolute
national sovereignty and the principle of non-interference, voluntary cooperation, informality,
decentralized consensus-based decision-making on the smallest common denominator and non-
confrontation. These norms served well until 1997 and provided political stability to the region.
19
Cf. Solingen: 1998: p. 6.

5
influence on the respective governments, which function as mediators between
domestic and regional politics. Consequently, the analysis of domestic politics is
crucial for understanding regional outcomes. Inspired by MacIntyre's "The Power of
Institutions"
20
and Solingen's "Regional Orders at Century's Dawn ­ Global and
Domestic Influences on Grand Strategy"
21
the analysis is focused on the domestic
level, on which it primarily identifies domestic interests, the institutions through
which interests are aggregated, and to what extent these ultimately influence
governments in order to shape regional economic integration analogous to their
interests. The great advantage of a combination of these two approaches is, that it is
able to reflect the interplay of a variety of economic and state actors and that it
"...offers an analytical pivot that allows the simultaneous consideration of
international and domestic political and economic aspects of a grand strategy [i.e.
state preferences]."
22
A coalitional approach facilitates the handling of a variety of different actors
and their underlying interests and, as demonstrated in the fourth Chapter, reduces the
complexity of analysis significantly. Institutional aspects are necessary for
identifying the degree of relative political influence of different actors, which finally
determine the extent, to which a respective coalition can exert political influence on
the decision-making process. This combination suits the Southeast Asian situation, in
which inter-elite coalitions play a crucial role in domestic struggles for, or against,
regional economic integration.
For combining coalitional-structuralist approaches, this study can be situated
within a much wider area of academic research concerned with rational choice
theories. Among the more prominent works are clearly Milner's "Interests,
Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations"
23
and
Aggarwal and Fogarty's very recent work "Between Regionalism and Globalism:
European Union Interregional Trade Strategies"
24
. Yet in general, these approaches
deal with European or "Western" concepts and are not directly applicable to a
Southeast Asian context. Yet, the goal of this thesis is to combine a deductive
approach with convincing empirical information within a framework, which suits the
special Southeast Asian context. Consequently, the information, on which this
20
Cf. MacIntyre: 2003.
21
Cf. Solingen: 1998.
22
Op.cit.: p. 8.
23
Cf. Milner: 1997.
24
Cf. Aggarwal and Fogarty: 2004.

6
research is grounded, necessarily covers a wide range of alternative works on
Southeast Asia.
The existing literature relevant for this research can, thus, be classified into
theoretical and empirical approaches. Apart from the theoretical approaches
introduced above, a theoretical focus is firstly put on economic sciences, in order to
define and explain economic interests. These include among others Balassa, Bender,
Buschmann and Skala.
25
A second group of theoretical approaches focus on
structuralist-institutionalist arguments, which identify underlying institutions and
socio-political structures as relevant for domestic influence. These include: Crone
and Doner, who focus on the state capacity of the Southeast Asian states, and more
recently, Bishop and Neumann, who contribute to the understanding of Southeast
Asian patronage and elite relationships.
26
Three kinds of empirical studies are employed for the analytical part of this
research. The first part analyses the domestic politics of the respective countries and
provides necessary information on the relevant economic and political actors. The
most important authors are introduced in Paragraph 1.4. In order to identify the
economic interests of the respective actors, as outlined in Chapter 2.2, the second
part comprises econometric studies, which survey the relative competitiveness of the
different economic sectors. Emphasis is put on the manufacturing and agribusiness
industries and on the services providers of the respective countries, which are most
relevant with regard to the free trade commitment of AFTA. These surveys, however,
are very scarce and do neither comprise all relevant economic sectors, nor do they
give hints about political influence of economic actors. Consequently, to a certain
extent, the analysis is based on assumptions. A third part covers both WTO and
AFTA documents, which provide evidence on economic political decision-making of
the respective countries and give data on how different products are treated under the
AFTA-framework (compare Chapter 3.2.3.1.). In this regard, a study conducted by
Bowie and Unger
27
adds valuable information about underlying interests and
economic policy choices of selected ASEAN countries.
25
Cf. Balassa: 1961; Bender: 2003; Buschmann: 1991; and Skala: 2003.
26
Cf. Bishop: 2003; Crone: 1995; Doner: 1991; and Neumann: 2002.
27
Cf. Bowie and Unger: 1997.

7
1.3. Scope and applicability of research
Though acknowledging that incentives other than economic ones might also
serve as explanations for changing state preferences of the ASEAN members towards
regional economic integration
28
, this analysis is focused on a monocausal approach.
Thus, in order to reduce the complexity of this thesis, only the economic interests of
domestically important actors
29
and their relative influence on central decision-
making will be considered. International economic developments will only be
considered to an extent which is necessary to explain the economic interests of the
respective actors.
As the thesis attempts to find out, why AFTA was founded, and argues, that
its foundation was a logic consequence deriving from previous adjustments of the
trade regimes of the respective countries, the scope of analysis covers a five-year,
pre-founding period of AFTA, which correlates with a period of economic recovery
starting in 1985, and its foundation phase and early implementation, which covers
the period 1991 to 1995 and correlates with the economic boom phase.
The focus of analysis is limited to Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand,
henceforth ASEAN Three, for the following reasons: Firstly, the group of ASEAN
Three comprises those founding members of AFTA, which have played a crucial role
during its founding phase (compare Chapter 3.2.2.). Furthermore, the studied
countries have experienced two similar eras of economic development. Ranging from
the 1960s to the early 1980s the first period was marked by import-
substitutionalisation. The second export-oriented period was initiated in the early to
mid-1980s, and finally paved the way for the foundation of AFTA (compare Chapter
3.1.). Additionally, these three countries are politically comparable to a very high
degree. Symptomatic for the ASEAN Three states is the omnipresence of patron-
client relations, which exert strong influence on political decision-making organs and
therefore erode state capacities (compare Chapters 3.1 and 4.2).
Actually, Brunei, the Philippines, and Singapore are also founding members
of AFTA, but they are excluded from further considerations. This can be justified by
the fact, that with regard to Brunei, relevant information is very scarce. Additionally,
the sultanate does not play a very important role within the ASEAN forum.
28
Cf. Tan: 1996: pp. 162-169: During the 1980s and 1990s ASEAN politics often seemed to respond
to changes of the international environment. In this regard, the academic debate contributes AFTA's
foundation to a balancing strategy of the ASEAN member countries towards the emerging regional
trade blocs in Europe and North America.
29
Chapter two will demonstrate that these `domestically important actors' refer to both the domestic
business and politico-bureaucratic elites and foreign investors.

8
Singapore, in contrast, is, as the economically most advanced country of the
region, of crucial importance for the AFTA process. Yet, the city state is
internationally regarded as one of the economically most liberalized countries in the
world
30
and displays high levels of state capacity
31
. Hence, domestic struggles pro or
contra regional economic integration are unlikely to be observed.
The Philippines, in contrast, is characterized by the same political and
economic structures as the ASEAN Three countries and was initially supposed to be
included in the analysis. After extensive research, however, it became evident, that
the Philippines did not play an active role in the founding process of AFTA. Instead,
it showed a more opportunistic, almost band-wagoning like behaviour towards
joining the free trade area.
32
Moreover, economically the Philippines is not very
comparable to the ASEAN Three, because during the observed time span it could
achieve a slight economic recovery with average growth rates of annually three per
cent only, which is rather poor compared to annually eight to nine per cent in the
case of the other three countries.
33
Most significantly however, it became apparent,
that, albeit domestic power struggles between different coalitions were conducted in
a very forceful way
34
, market liberalization did not take place, because a liberal-
oriented coalition was able to overcome protectionist pressures. Instead, external
factors resulted in a major change of the Philippines preferences towards joining
AFTA. First of all, international lending organizations, most prominently the World
Bank and the IMF, threatened to freeze funds, that were granted to the government, if
it was not willing to adopt policy reforms promoting economic openness.
35
Secondly,
in 1991, the treaties with the USA on the two U.S. military bases were not prolonged.
This significantly reduced the inflow of urgently needed foreign capital into the
Philippine economy and most importantly into the pockets of the Philippine
oligarchy, at a time, when the economy contracted by nine per cent.
36
New sources
for income generation had to be found. Thirdly, impressed by the economic
achievements of their neighbour countries, under Aquino's successor Ramos, the
30
Cf. Südostasien Aktuell: January 1999:p. 17.
31
Cf. Mackie: 1988: pp. 295; 321-323.
32
Cf. Leifer: 1996: p. 29; Schmidt: 2001: p. 21.
33
Cf. Saldana: 2001: p. 158.
34
Though initially aiming at reforming the country economically and politically the Philippine
President Aquino could not overcome the power of the oligarchic elite. Politics during her time in
office, that is between 1986 and 1991, were thus punctuated by a succession of coup attempts,
culminating in a large, bloody, and well-financed attempt in December 1989, which gave Aquino no
political space to target any reforms.
35
Cf. Bowie and Unger: 1997: p. 126; Diakono-Pascual: 2000: pp. 2-3.
36
Cf. Hutchcroft: 1996.

9
government finally opted for a gradual trade liberalization.
37
To summarize, these
external factors, especially the first two, were so dominant, that they had overlain the
economic interests of domestic actors and perpetuated trade liberalization since the
1990s. Therefore, coalition forming and domestic power struggles for political
predominance, on which the analysis is grounded, have been overshadowed.
Unfortunately, the theoretical framework, as outlined in Chapter two, is not able to
capture these external factors, which, in the case of the Philippines, functioned as
catalysts for trade liberalization.
The CLMV-countries
38
are excluded from analysis, because they were not
members of ASEAN and AFTA during the observed time span.
As such, the theoretical framework, on which this thesis is grounded, is
applicable to basically all cases, in which countries, for a variety of reasons, want to
overcome protectionism and form regional economic integration schemes. With
regard to Southeast Asia, the theoretical approach and the empirical findings can be
extended, to include the more recent developments of regional economic integration.
It is applicable to the analysis of the enlargement of AFTA by the CLMV-countries
as well as by additional programmes. Moreover, in East Asia, the 21
st
century has
witnessed the emergence of cross-regional free trade arrangements, such as the
recently founded China-ASEAN Free Trade Area (CAFTA) and the linking of AFTA
with Australia and New Zealand. The ASEAN-member states' positions can be
analysed by this framework as well.
Apart from the very broad applicability of this approach, it, nevertheless,
faces some limitations. First of all, it is not able to deal with major external factors,
which overshadow domestic coalition forming and political power struggles, as
already demonstrated in the case of the Philippines. Whenever countries are
predominantly dependent on foreign lending agencies, which strongly interfere in
political decision-making, economic adjustments, as adopted by the governments,
cannot be analysed with this approach. Moreover, during the early period of regional
economic integration, in which democratic participation of the major parts of the
ASEAN Three societies in economic decision-making was rather marginal, their
interests could be easily excluded from further consideration. With proceeding
37
Ibid.
38
CLMV refers to ASEAN's newcomers Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar, and Vietnam.

10
democratisation, however, these interests need to be considered as well. This would
increase the scope of research drastically.
1.4. Research
method
The method applied to answer the research questions is based on a qualitative
research, surveying secondary literature.
Given a Southeast Asian business context, which is characterized by
patronage relationships (compare Chapters 2.2.2.1. and 3.1.), the identification of
politico-business connections is most important for determining political influence,
which in this study is assumed to play a crucial role for the foundation and
implementation of AFTA. Therefore, the analysis, provided in the fourth chapter,
relies on a wide range of secondary literature, which uncovers the relationships
between the major business groups of the respective countries and high ranking
politicians. The most important works are enlisted as follows: The analysis of
Indonesian politico-business connections and economic interests is based on books
written and/or published by Basri and Hill, Emmerson, Case, MacIntyre, Soesastro
and Basri, and Winters.
39
In the case of Malaysia, the analysis is based on various
works written by Case, Gomez, and Jomo.
40
Most of the valuable information on
Thailand derives from a range of books written by Laothamatas, Pasuk, and Baker.
41
These literary works have been scanned in order to find any hints about
business-politico connections. As `politically connected' can be regarded any
business actors, who entertain close ­ be it friendship or business-dominated ­
relationships to government officials and high-ranking bureaucrats. These are those
business actors, who are able to exert high degrees of political influence on
governments. Moreover, as a direct influence of economic actors on the AFTA
process cannot be proven, domestic economic policies will be compared with the
foundation and implementation of AFTA. Based on the observations, that in
Southeast Asia economic actors can influence domestic legislation, but cannot
directly affect regional economic integration, this comparison serves as a substitute
for direct influence on the regional level. Depending on the data available, the
39
Cf. Basri and Hill: 2004; Emmerson: 1999; Case: 2002; MacIntyre: 1992; Soesastro and Basri:
2005; and Winters: 1996
40
Cf. Case: 2003; Gomez: 2005; Gomez and Jomo: 1997; Jomo et al.: 1997.
41
Cf. Laothamatas: 1988; Pasuk: 1992 and 1994; Pasuk and Baker: 1998 and 2000.

11
Appendixes two to four list the biggest 33-90 business conglomerates of the
respective countries, their political connectedness, the sectors in which they have
their main businesses, their degree of competitiveness and export-import-orientation
­ whenever available ­, government-induced protectionist measures ­ if applicable ­,
and their treatment under AFTA.
Using the analyses of the authors enumerated above, to identify political
connections and the influence of businesses on policy-making in a way that either
promotes or opposes economic liberalization, has two limitations: Firstly, the authors
do not claim to include every business-political connection, that might be relevant.
Consequently, these lists cannot claim to include all relevant business-political
connections. This weakness, however is not too problematic, because these authors
focus on those companies with the strongest political linkages. This focus is
consistent with the approach of this thesis, namely to identify the economic interests
of politically relevant actors. Secondly, throughout the observed time-span,
ownership changes occurred quite regularly and the companies shifted their focus of
operation to different sectors.
42
These complex shifts cannot be entirely reflected by
the Appendixes. Again, this limitation is not truly troublesome, because ownership
changes were likely to remain within the politico-business elites, and if shifts in
economic activity of the respective companies occurred, these displayed a common
pattern, that is from manufacturing to services. Consequently, the lists can be
regarded as representative for the most important business-political connections and
for business influence on political decision-making with regard to shaping AFTA.
In any case, it cannot be claimed, that this thesis has taken a random sample
of companies, of their official relations, and of economic policy choices, as every
effort has been made to select important state-owned, and private ­ both foreign- and
domestic-owned ­ companies, key policies and main patterns of foreign investment
to make the analysis as solid and convincing as possible.
1.5. Content
outline
Chapter two will provide a theoretical basis for this analysis. After briefly
explaining the theoretical effects, which trade liberalization has on formerly
protected markets, it will introduce the most important concepts, `economic
42
Compare, for instance, Gomez and Jomo: 1997.

12
interests', `coalitions', `political institutions', `political influence' and `state
capacity', which determine the independent, intervening, and dependent variables.
Chapter three has a twofold focus, which serves to offer the reader first
insights into the early economic development of the ASEAN Three countries on the
one hand, and then switch to the promotion of economic cooperation and integration,
which culminated in the foundation of AFTA on the other hand. Throughout the first
part of this chapter, patronage will be introduced as the predominant socio-political
institution, which underlies all social relationships of the studied countries and which
is crucial for determining political influence. Further, the relevant politico-economic
elites, whose interests shape the economic development of the respective countries
will be introduced on a country-to-country basis. This introduction is necessary for
two reasons: first, to understand the importance of AFTA as a turning point in
regional economic integration, second, to understand coalitional power struggles
observable during the founding and implementation phase of AFTA.
Chapter four, finally, comprises the analytical part of this thesis. The analysis
is focused on identifying the economic interests of the relevant actors. It combines
the coalitional approach, which will significantly reduce the complexity of a variety
of diverging economic interests, that are expressed by different state and business
actors, with the institutional approach, which serves to determine the degrees of
relative political influence of the various actors and, consequently, that of each
coalition. Power struggles over political predominance will become apparent. In this
regard, Chapter 4.1. will elaborate on the crucial importance of foreign direct
investment (FDI) and the changing economic interests of foreign investors. It will
highlight the role, which foreign investors played, for the foundation of AFTA.
Chapter 4.2. will proceed to examine country-specific factors of the three countries
respectively. Here, detailed information about the business and bureaucratic interests
and their respective degrees of political influence on shaping economic decision-
making with regard to trade liberalization will be provided in a country-to-country
study. Correlations between domestic policies and the foundation and
institutionalization of AFTA will become apparent.
Chapter five, finally, summarizes the arguments of the previous chapters and
demonstrates, that the foundation of AFTA was preceded by political pressures of the
internationalist coalitions of the three countries, and that its institutional design
served as a compromise between nationalist and internationalist coalitions. In
addition, Chapter five will assess the usefulness of the applied theoretical framework.

13
2. Theoretical Framework
Since the thesis is aimed at analysing the influence of domestic interests on
ASEAN decision-makers with regard to regional economic integration ­ here
represented by AFTA, it is necessary to understand, that economic integration is a
very controversially debated issue in economies, which were used to being highly
protected from import-competition. Therefore, before outlining the theoretical
framework, it is useful to demonstrate, which theoretical effects regional economic
integration has on formerly protected markets.
2.1. Regional Economic Integration in Theory
Economic sciences distinguish between economic cooperation and
integration. Economic cooperation refers to the voluntary participation in selective
economic areas only, which Hund calls "inter-governmental minimalism".
43
Partaking countries exit the cooperation agreement whenever trade negotiations seem
to disproportionately affect their economies. Regional economic integration, in
contrast, can be defined as the political integration of countries belonging to the same
region, by implementing group-specific institutions, which govern group-behaviour
and by allowing trade concessions, which positively influence intra-regional
economic transactions.
44
Theoretically, regional economic integration aims at establishing a regional
trade regime, which reflects the characteristics of free trade as genuinely as possible.
The economic sciences distinguish between tradable and non-tradable sectors. Under
free trade conditions most of the products and services of a respective economy can
be and are traded. Only a very limited number of goods and services, such as
construction and infrastructure, are not traded, not because they are protected from
trade, but because they are immobile. That means that, under free trade conditions, a
segmentation of the economy into tradable and non-tradable sector would
approximately look like this:
Figure 2.1
Economic segmentation under free trade conditions
Tradable sector
Non-tradable
sector
Source: Author
43
Hund: 2003: p. 39.
44
Cf. Skala: 2003: p. 61.

14
True free trade, however, does not occur in reality. Instead, markets ­
whether liberalized or protected ­ are the outcomes of lobbyism, of economic
interests and often of ideological constraints. Consequently, the economy does no
longer display a natural segmentation into tradable and non-tradable sector, in
accordance to the mobility of goods and services, but is segmented into a
competitive, tradable sector and an uncompetitive non-tradable sector.
45
That means,
that uncompetitive domestic producers are artificially protected from foreign
competition, although their products are mobile and could be traded. It is therefore
more appropriate to substitute the terms tradable and non-tradable with liberalized
and protected, as the latter two terms already suggest political manipulation.
Depending on the degree of manipulation, any deviation from the ideal-type
proportion between the two sectors is possible. With regard to the ASEAN Three
countries' high level of protectionism at the beginning of the 1980s, the above
displayed market segmentation might have approximately looked like this:
Figure 2.2
Economic segmentation under protectionist conditions
Liberalized
sector
Protected sector
Source: Author
In this regard, regional economic integration schemes aim at expanding the
scope of the liberalized sector until it comes close to the ideal-type proportion
outlined in figure 2.1. Various stages of regional economic integration can be
distinguished according to their degree of institutionalization: the preferential trade
arrangement, the free trade area, the tariff union, the common market and the
economic union.
46
In this regard, the ASEAN Free Trade Area represents a low grade of
economic integration. Its aim is to abolish trade barriers among the participating
countries, be it tariffs or non-tariff barriers. The member countries are therefore
required to gradually liberalize their economies through adjustments of their
domestic tariff systems. Each political movement towards liberalization, however,
intensifies trade competition. Those more competitive businesses will benefit from
competition, while intensified competition endangers the economic interests of those
less competitive companies, which were once protected by trade barriers. Under
45
Cf. Bowie and Unger: 1997: p. 1; Jayasuriya: 2001: p. 3.
46
Cf. Balassa: 1961; Buschmann: 1991. p. 10

15
these circumstances regional economic integration will create `winners and losers'
among the domestic businesses.
47
2.2. Interests,
coalitions,
and
political influence in theory
Central to this thesis is the assumption, that the foundation and
implementation of AFTA was, to a large extent, determined by the economic
interests of politically dominant economic actors. The following paragraphs will
therefore, firstly identify the interests of domestic and transnational economic actors,
the coalitions which these actors form, and secondly, the socio-political institutions
through which interests are politically represented. Thirdly, these findings will be
combined to examine the influence of domestic and transnational economic actors on
the central decision-making organs, which will subsequently translate the most
influential interests into economic policies. These economic policies will then be
compared with the AFTA process and serve as a substitute of direct political
influence of domestic actors on regional economic integration. In this regard, much
emphasis is laid on domestic economic policy-making.
2.2.1.
Economic interests and coalition-forming
Patzelt defines interest as
"[v]erhaltensorientiertes Ziel oder Bedürfnis von einzelnen oder Gruppen im
sozialen Umfeld. [...]. Interessen sind Verhaltensdispositionen; sie sind Ziele oder
Bedürfnisse, aus einer Sache echten oder vermeintlichen Nutzen zu ziehen; und sie
sind Reaktionen eines Akteurs auf Gegebenheiten eines sozialen Umfelds"
48
.
In this context, interest will exclusively refer to the economic interests of
domestically relevant actors. These are domestic business and politico-bureaucratic
actors and foreign investors.
47
Cf. Bender: 2003: pp. 475 ­ 560: According to classic and neo-classic economic theories, trade
liberalization generates trade creation and trade diversion effects in all partaking economies. Trade
creation is generally regarded as a positive effect. All economies participating in economic
cooperation schemes can benefit from trade, as they can obtain those categories of goods, which they
are not able to produce themselves effectively. Trade diversion means, that under free trade conditions
the less competitive producers, that is those who produce at high costs, suffer from cheaper
competitors, as the latter redirect consumption from the more expensive products to their own cheaper
substitutes. This negative side-effect of trade liberalization is usually put forward to justify economic
protectionism.
48
Patzelt: 2001: p. 505.

16
However, according to Sullivan "business is not a monolith".
49
Indeed, a wide
range of economic interests can be attributed to various parts of the business
community of the ASEAN member states. One basic cleavage separates the interests
of domestic, usually import-competing businesses from those of foreign-owned,
predominantly export-competitive companies. Whereas the former can increase their
profits under import-substituting and protectionist conditions, the latter promote
trade liberalization. A second difference can be made between state-owned
enterprises and privately-run businesses. As state-owned enterprises often lack the
required levels of competitiveness, they are more likely to benefit from trade
protection and state subsidies. In contrast, privately-owned companies are more
likely to derive their competitiveness from managerial skills rather than from state
intervention. Hence, they are more likely to favour trade liberalization. With regard
to Southeast Asia, a third divide must also be considered. Due to the persistence of
patronage systems and clientelistic structures, a narrow, politically well-connected
business elite is able to exert a high level of influence on economic policy choices
and to lobby for particularistic protection, while other economic actors are widely
excluded from political participation.
50
The economic interests of business actors are not fixed permanently. Instead,
their interests alter according to changes in the overall economy, trends in domestic
and international markets, as well as in response to political decisions. Chapter three
will demonstrate that the ASEAN Three countries experienced major shifts of their
respective economic and political environments during the early to mid-1980s, which
­ as will be discussed in detail in the chapters three and four ­ have resulted in
greater trade liberalization. Consequently, the business actors were required to
respond to these economic changes. In this regard, the economic actors displayed
three different reactions: They either supported regional economic integration, in the
case that they were positively affected; they opposed regional economic integration,
in the case that they were negatively affected; or they withdrew their economic
activities from those sectors, in which the business environment was no longer
favourable, and shifted them to production sites, which were more promising.
Especially those foreign investors as well as domestic owners of mobile capital can
exert high levels of influence on political decision-making as they can threaten to
49
Sullivan: 2002: p. 1.
50
Op.cit.: pp. 1-3.

17
divest their capital.
51
With regard to Southeast Asia, Chapter 4.2 will demonstrate,
that all three reactions could be observed.
For the politically well-connected business elites of the Southeast Asian
countries political participation is easy to achieve, as patronage provides them with
the opportunity to establish very personal and direct relationships to politicians.
Singular influence, however, might not be enough to determine the outcome of
economic policies. Then, coalition-building is a ready strategy to promote or delay
reform.
52
In this regard, Solingen defines coalitions as
"... policy networks spanning state and private political actors". [...] "Actors join
forces in coalitions when their interests converge and tradeoffs are attractive, in
order to safeguard those interests against alternative coalitions"
53
According to economic interests, Solingen distinguishes between two ideal-
type coalitions: the competitive and internationally-oriented coalition ­ further
addressed as internationalists ­ which will predominantly benefit from regional
economic integration and the less competitive inward-oriented coalitions ­ further
called nationalists ­ whose economic profits will be threatened.
54
Especially in
transitional economies, such as those of the ASEAN Three countries, Chapter 4.2.
demonstrates, that the business sectors are divided along the lines discussed above.
2.2.1.1.
The internationalist coalition
An internationalist coalition comprises those economic actors, be it private or
state agents, who for various reasons promote economic reforms towards trade
liberalization. One can assume, that an internationalist coalition will, thus, include
owners, both domestic and foreign, of competitive, export-oriented assets, especially
those, who are interested in entering world markets and are dependent on imports, or
who are already involved in foreign trade. Chapter three will outline the importance
of foreign direct investment (FDI) for the Southeast Asian countries to achieve
economic growth. Consequently, FDI can be regarded as vitally important for
domestic interests. The state agencies, which promote trade liberalization will be
further called technocrats.
51
Cf. Solingen: 1998: pp. 24-25; Winters: 1996: p. 42.
52
Cf. Sullivan: 2002: pp. 2-4.
53
Solingen: 1998: p. 9 and p. 11, respectively.
54
Op.cit.: p. 3

18
2.2.1.2. The
nationalist
coalition
A nationalist coalition comprises those both private and state actors, who
"(...) have an inherent affinity with import-substituting models of industrialization
and classical populist programmes involving a strong, active government (...)",
which makes them "(...) perceive regional cooperative outcomes as weakening
(...)".
55
Nationalist coalitions are likely to include producers of import-competing products
and services, and state-owned enterprises.
56
Generally, a particularly strong
opposition to trade liberalization can be expected to be put forward by the
government-owned enterprises. In patronage systems these will find strong support
by those business elites, which entertain close business relations with the
government.
57
The state agencies, which oppose trade liberalization are further
addressed as nationalist conservatives. They are strongest as long as they can gather
necessary financial resources to maintain their policies of protectionism.
58
Table 2.1 summarises the above-mentioned estimates about the interests of
domestic actors and their assumed coalition membership.
Table 2.1
Interests, coalition-forming and political influence in theory
Coalition
Actor
Interests
Nationalist Internationalist
Export-oriented businesses
Trade liberalization
exclusively
Foreign investors
Trade liberalization
exclusively
Technocrats
Trade liberalization
exclusively
Import-competing businesses Protection
exclusively
Conservatives
State intervention
exclusively
Source: Author
With regard to Southeast Asia, the existence of huge business conglomerates
render the analysis of business interests extremely difficult. In the possession of the
respective elite members, these conglomerates comprise networks of both
competitive and uncompetitive affiliates, operating in a range of various business
sectors. Accordingly, it is difficult to distinguish between those domestic actors,
favouring trade liberalization, and those, favouring protectionism. Instead,
conglomerates face a very complex set of interests to be addressed through economic
55
Solingen: 1998: pp. 32; 41.
56
Op.cit.: pp. 22; 24.
57
Cf. Sullivan: 2002: p. 3.
58
Solingen: 1998: p. 52.

19
policies.
59
Domestic actors support trade liberalization of their competitive export-
oriented enterprises, while insisting on protectionism of the uncompetitive firms.
60
In
other words, internationalist interests are combined with nationalist interests and
render a case-to-case analysis necessary. This is provided in Chapter 4.2.
2.2.2.
Political institutions, political influence and state capacity
According to Macintyre
"[i]nstitutions [emphasis added] are constraints that shape behaviour in all sorts of
areas of human activity, stretching from social interaction to economic exchange to
international cooperation."
61
Political institutions determine the manner, in which leadership is organized, state
authority exercised, and social interests aggregated and represented.
62
Hence,
political institutions are crucial for regulating social influence and for determining
the degree of state capacity.
Influence, in its broadest political sense, can be defined as the power of
certain social actors relative to that of other constituents to direct political decision-
making, in a way that is best suitable for their interests.
63
With regard to Southeast
Asia, the degree of political influence is determined by an actor's closeness to high
ranking politicians.
Political sciences subdivide state capacity into political and bureaucratic
capacity. Emmerson defines political capacity as "adaptability in problem solving"
64
.
This definition refers to a government's ability, competence, and cohesiveness to
formulate and implement policies isolated from particularistic influences, such as
rent-seeking demands
65
and lobbyism
66
, yet to maintain an adequate level of
embeddedness with society, to be able to further social goals and to make sure that
policy goals align with market capabilities. Bureaucratic capacity refers to the
competence and cohesiveness of the bureaucratic apparatus in planning the detailed
59
Cf. Solingen: 1998: p. 23.
60
Cf. Case: 2003: 3-5; and Jayasuriya: 2001: pp. 2-5.
61
Macintyre: 2003. p. 2.
62
Op.cit.: p. 1.
63
Cf. Solingen: 1998: p. 20.
64
Quoted in Crone: 1988: p. 55.
65
Cf. Gomez and Jomo: 1997: p. 6, who define rent-seeking "as ways of making profit (that is,
income) by undertaking activities which are directly unproductive; [as] for example direct political
activity, lobbying, and bribes [which] increase in markets where competition is artificially limited by
government."
66
Schubert and Klein: 2003: p. 181, define lobbyism as the act of interest groups or single actors to
influence political decision-making in a way, that best suits their interests. This influence can be
exerted by a variety of different means.

20
implementation of domestic policies.
67
With regard to those political systems, which
are typical for the ASEAN Three countries, political representation takes place in a
more socially exclusive way.
Moreover, in order to identify the respective actors' influence on political
decision-making, it is necessary to distinguish between informal and formal political
institutions, which both are relevant for understanding political influence. Informal
institutions refer to the political culture of Southeast Asian societies, which are based
on patronage systems and on the socio-political predominance of elites. Formal
institutions refer to the political systems of the respective countries. Given the rather
empirical character of institutions, patronage and elites will be dealt with at greater
length in Chapter 3.1. At this point, it is however, important to consider, that
patronage is not a pluralist system. The first consequence of the predominance of
patronage is that the government and its executive branches mainly pursue policies,
which suit the particularistic interests of the elites.
68
The second consequence is, that
the studied countries display relatively high levels of political insulation from public
pressure.
69
Subsequently, the bias of patronage systems narrows the research
drastically, as only the economic interests of the elites need to be examined.
The formal institutional architecture refers to the respective political systems
­ that is Thailand's parliamentary system, Malaysia's hegemonic one-party system
and Indonesia's authoritarian regime, which are dealt with at greater length in the
chapters 4.2.1. to 4.2.3.
70
As interest coalitions seek to influence political decision-
making, at this point, it is important to understand the legislative and executive ways
through which economic policies are passed and implemented, and at which points
political influence is possible.
2.2.3. The independent and the intervening variables
The economic interests of individual actors can change with economic
development. In order to maintain economic interests fixed, a coalitional approach
can be very usefully employed as a theoretical model, which can overcome the
67
Cf. Bishop: 2003: p. 71.
68
Cf. Case: 2002: p. 205.
69
For instance see Bello, Cunningham and Li (1998); McCargo (2002); Rigg (2003); Serrano and
Marasigan
(2004): Worker rights have been rigorously constrained, membership in and activism of
unions was long either prohibited or severely constrained. Farmers have no political influence,
protests if there were any were regulated through military intervention.
70
Cf. MacIntyre: 2003: pp. 43-49.

21
problematic of changing economic interests. Economic interests are simply
represented by the respective coalitions, within which membership is fluid. This
means, that as a whole the respective coalition represents certain type economic
interests, namely either those pro, or those contra trade liberalization. As soon as the
interests of individual actors change significantly, these actors will be counted to the
alternative coalition.
The economic interests of the nationalist coalition are treated as the
independent variable I, whereas the economic interests of the internationalist
coalition are fixed as the independent variable II.
Political institutions filter and mediate an "...array of contending interests
seeking policy satisfaction...".
71
They are crucial for determining the relative
influence of coalitions, for which political institutions can either function as a
catalyst or as a hindrance. Political institutions will therefore serve to operationalize
political influence.
Political institutions are consequently treated as the intervening variable.
This choice can be justified by the fact, that the analysis is subdivided into
short time intervals, which correlate with either government changes ­ in the case of
Thailand ­ or with major changes in the government's overall strategy towards
economic developments ­ in the cases of Indonesia and Malaysia. Government
changes can have major implications for the representation of domestic interests,
especially in socio-political systems, like patronage, which stress the importance of
personal relationships. Whenever possible, these personal connections between
business actors and politicians will be uncovered and provide indicators for
measuring influence. The Appendixes two to four provide a very comprehensive
overview of the economic actors and their connections to high-ranking politicians.
Given the short time intervals, the probability of structural changes within the
relevant domestic political institutions can be reduced significantly.
71
MacIntyre: 2003: p. 51.

22
2.2.4.
The dependent variable
This thesis aims at analysing the influence of domestic interests on political
decision-making with regard to regional economic integration. Based on the
assumption, that regional economic integration is to a large extent determined by
domestic interests, political decision-making the aggregated economic interests of
the politically relevant actors. In this regard, the government serves as a mere
representative institution, which is
"(...) constantly subject to capture and recapture, construction and reconstruction by
coalitions of social actors"
72
.
Political institutions both formal and informal as outlined above constitute the
"critical transmission belt"
73
by which the interests of social actors are translated into
policies, which finally represent political decision-making.
Political decision-making with regard to regional economic integration, here
represented by AFTA, is therefore treated as the dependent variable.
Yet, `political decision-making' is not operable. This problem, however, can
be easily put aside. As already outlined in Chapter 2.1, regional economic integration
in the form of a free trade area requires the implementation on the domestic level
through economic policies, which adjust the domestic trade regime. That means, that
the domestic economy needs to be liberalized through economic policies on a
domestic level. Economic policies, which represent the outcome of political
decision-making are operable. It is relatively easy to judge economic policies on the
basis, whether they enhance or reduce the process of trade liberalization, and when
compared with the AFTA process, provide the necessary evidence, if and to what
extent domestic interests influence regional economic integration. Moreover, as a
direct influence of economically relevant actors on the AFTA process is not
observable, economic policies will be compared with the institutionalization of
AFTA. The correlation between domestic policies and the particular treatment of
certain items under the AFTA schedule, as introduced in more details in Chapter 3.2.
will then provide measurable data about the interference of domestic actors
Economic policy choice is employed as the operational variable for political
decision-making.
72
Moravcsik: 1997: pp. 517-518.
73
Op.cit.: p. 518.

23
2.3. Conclusion
Having introduced the effects of regional economic integration on domestic
interests, the interplay of domestic coalitions, and their relative influence on
decision-making, it is possible to identify the policy choices on a spectrum ranging
from absolute trade liberalization, that is a comprehensive scope of AFTA, at the one
end to protectionism, which equals a rather limited scope of AFTA, at the other end.
Figure 2.3 demonstrates the basic cleavage between the interests represented
by internationalist and nationalist coalitions for economic liberalization and
protectionism respectively. Depending on each coalition's degree of political
influence, the relatively stronger coalition will persuade the government to pursue
those policies out of a spectrum of various policy choices, ranging from trade
liberalization and protectionism, which best suits their interests. The government's
decision, to either pursue policies towards trade liberalization or towards
protectionism, will ultimately demonstrate a change of state preferences towards
regional economic integration.
Figure 2.3 C
oalitional i
n
fluence on political decision-making and the policy choice
Political decision-making organ
Degree of influence??? Degree of influence???
Internationalist coalition Nationalist coalition
??? Policy choice ???
Trade liberalization Protectionism
(comprehensive scope of AFTA) (limited scope of AFTA)
Legend: : political influence : spectrum of policy choices
Source: Author
With regard to the independent variables I and II, two hypotheses (H1 and
H2) can be put forward.
H1: Policy choices are unlikely to move in the direction of trade
liberalization, that is towards a comprehensive scope of AFTA, when the influence
of the nationalist coalition is stronger than that of the internationalist coalition.
H2: Policy choices are more likely to move in the direction of trade
liberalization, that is towards a comprehensive scope of AFTA, when the influence
of the internationalist coalition is stronger than that of the nationalist coalition.
Figure 2.4 displays the above-mentioned hypotheses and summarises the estimation

24
about the likeliness of policy choices aimed at trade liberalization given varying
degrees of influence of the two opposing coalitions. The situation is unambiguous,
when one coalition has the stronger influence than the other. However, stalemates
can occur, when no coalition is able to maintain the stronger influence on decision-
making. Under these circumstances, one possible reaction is to achieve a
compromise by dividing the spheres of influence on different economic sectors.
74
The crucial point, however, is that politicians often have to adopt balancing policy
choices, particularly when policy adjustments involve a shift from distributive aims
to economic growth.
Figure 2.4
Political influence and economic policy choices
Independent Variable II
Economic interests of
the internationalist coalition
Intervening
Variable
political influence
strong
weak
strong
Stalemate or
Compromise
Contra AFTA
Independent
Variable
I
Interests of the
nationalist coalition
weak
Pro AFTA
Indecisive,
no influence
Source: Author
What basically needs to be done in order to understand the dynamics of the
Southeast Asian regional economic integration, is first of all, to identify domestic
interests for or against trade liberalization/AFTA; second, to analyse the extent, to
which these interests influence political decision-making and policy outcome;
thirdly, to analyse the extent, to which economic policy choices aim at trade
liberalization or trade protection; and fourthly, as direct influence of economic actors
on AFTA as such is not observable, to compare domestic policy choices with the
foundation, institutional design and implementation process of AFTA. As this thesis
argues, that AFTA was preceded by adjustments of the respective trade regimes
towards trade liberalization, and can consequently be regarded as a logic
consequence of these adjustments, the analysis of domestic policies will also
comprise AFTA's pre-founding phase. This analysis is carried out in the fourth
chapter. The next chapter will introduce the reader to the economic development of
the ASEAN Three countries, which preceded the observed time span.
74
Cf. Solingen: 1998: pp. 53-54.
Policy
choice?

25
3. Economic development and regional economic integration
Chapter 2.1. has outlined, that markets are artificial products of political
manipulation. In Southeast Asia, economic policies have been manipulated by
patronage demands to a significant extent throughout approximately the last forty
years.
75
During this period the ASEAN Three economies have undergone two
different stages of economic development: import-substitution
76
followed by export-
promotion
77
. Moreover, the economic policies adopted by the ASEAN Three
governments have been more focused on distributive rather than on growth issues.
Economic interests are therefore likely to reflect this manipulation to a very large
extent. Chapter 3.1 will emphasise the extent, to which patronage ­ as the
predominant socio-political institution, that determines political influence ­ and the
politico-economic elites ­ as the relevant domestic actors ­ have shaped the
economic development of the respective countries. Chapter 3.2 will switch to
regional economic cooperation and integration, which was long dominated by
protectionist attitudes. In anticipation of Chapter four, the founding and
implementation process of AFTA will be already laid out. The importance of AFTA
as a turning point in regional economic integration will be highlighted.
3.1. Overview: patronage and early economic development
In Southeast Asia, informal institutions comprise the very traditional concepts
of political power and representation, which are expressed through patronage
networks and inter-elite relationships. Although patronage is not entirely unique to
Southeast Asian societies, this system of social exchange has strong historical roots
in the region and is remarkably all-encompassing to present day.
78
Indeed, patronage
has shaped social and state actors and is the underlying socio-political institution of
75
Bowie and Unger: 1997: have conducted a decisive study on economic policy choices of the
ASEAN Three in response to international economic changes. One of their findings is, that at least
since the 1970s economic policies have been trying to reflect particularistic demands as long as the
state's financial resources were not absolutely constrained.
76
Import-substitution is an economic strategy of promoting those industrial sectors which in the mid-
to long-term will substitute imported products with domestically produced goods and render the
economy less dependent on external trade.
77
Export-promotion is the opposite strategy of economic development. Export-oriented industrial
sectors will be promoted so that they can increase competitive advantages and succeed in international
trade. Ultimately, trade surpluses will benefit the economy through increased tax payments and an
expansion of economic activities which benefits the domestic labour force.
78
For a comprehensive description of the socio-historic roots of patronage in Southeast Asia see:
Neumann: 2002.

Details

Seiten
Erscheinungsform
Originalausgabe
Jahr
2006
ISBN (eBook)
9783832498658
ISBN (Paperback)
9783838698656
Dateigröße
1.2 MB
Sprache
Englisch
Institution / Hochschule
Universität Münster – Philosophische Fakultät, Politikwissenschaft
Note
1,3
Schlagworte
asean free trade area afta rational choice theorie lobbyismus interessenverband
Zurück

Titel: The Influence of Domestic Interests on ASEAN politics
book preview page numper 1
book preview page numper 2
book preview page numper 3
book preview page numper 4
book preview page numper 5
book preview page numper 6
book preview page numper 7
book preview page numper 8
book preview page numper 9
book preview page numper 10
book preview page numper 11
book preview page numper 12
book preview page numper 13
book preview page numper 14
book preview page numper 15
book preview page numper 16
book preview page numper 17
book preview page numper 18
book preview page numper 19
book preview page numper 20
book preview page numper 21
book preview page numper 22
book preview page numper 23
book preview page numper 24
book preview page numper 25
book preview page numper 26
book preview page numper 27
book preview page numper 28
book preview page numper 29
book preview page numper 30
book preview page numper 31
book preview page numper 32
book preview page numper 33
161 Seiten
Cookie-Einstellungen