Lade Inhalt...

Economic Liberalization and Domestic Instability

A Comparative Study

©2003 Diplomarbeit 109 Seiten

Zusammenfassung

Inhaltsangabe:Abstract:
During the nineties globalization has become one of the most disputed issues in the social sciences and a lively debate about its possible detrimental or beneficial consequences is going on. Among economists there exists the general consensus that global economic integration enhances welfare through market allocations that are assumed to be efficient. The majority of papers hereby concentrate on explaining what the causes for the increasing economic liberalization are, the feasibility of these reforms, limiting the debate to the question of correct sequencing of the distinct measures, or to the causes of either their success or failure. Another phenomena of the last decade has been the increasing amount of armed intrastate conflicts around the world which reached its peak in the early 1990s. Although economic aspects gained in interest as roots of internal war, economic liberalization per se was not considered as a causal factor.
This study therefore examines the question of whether economic liberalization is likely to fan the flames of domestic violent conflict, thereby distinguishing between long-term and short-term consequences of this process. I assume that in the long-term economic liberalization has a pacifying effect as the abolition of trade barriers fosters export-led growth. On the contrary, in the short-term, after an economic reform has been introduced, distributional effects will have a major impact on society, causing winners and losers. This situation is likely to trigger domestic instability and violent conflict if the winners are not able or willing to compensate the losers for their economic losses. To explain cleavages arising in society, this study adds an institutional perspective to Rogowski’s model based on the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem and highlights it with an exemplary application with the Rubinstein Model. I illustrate the propositions derived from this model by presenting the case of Guinea-Bissau. Testing statistically the causal mechanism between economic liberalization and domestic conflict and intervening factors of political, sociological, and economical kinds, it furthermore engages in comparative work in a dual sense: the study moves across different levels of analysis and compares the three statistical tools ordinary logit, random effects logit and general estimating equation. It first starts with a sample comprising 90 developing countries for the time period of 1978 to 1998 and focuses […]

Leseprobe

Inhaltsverzeichnis


ID 9379
Wiesehomeier, Nina:
Economic Liberalization and Domestic Instability - A Comparative Study
Druck Diplomica GmbH, Hamburg, 2006
Zugl.: Universität Konstanz, Diplomarbeit, 2003
Dieses Werk ist urheberrechtlich geschützt. Die dadurch begründeten Rechte,
insbesondere die der Übersetzung, des Nachdrucks, des Vortrags, der Entnahme von
Abbildungen und Tabellen, der Funksendung, der Mikroverfilmung oder der
Vervielfältigung auf anderen Wegen und der Speicherung in Datenverarbeitungsanlagen,
bleiben, auch bei nur auszugsweiser Verwertung, vorbehalten. Eine Vervielfältigung
dieses Werkes oder von Teilen dieses Werkes ist auch im Einzelfall nur in den Grenzen
der gesetzlichen Bestimmungen des Urheberrechtsgesetzes der Bundesrepublik
Deutschland in der jeweils geltenden Fassung zulässig. Sie ist grundsätzlich
vergütungspflichtig. Zuwiderhandlungen unterliegen den Strafbestimmungen des
Urheberrechtes.
Die Wiedergabe von Gebrauchsnamen, Handelsnamen, Warenbezeichnungen usw. in
diesem Werk berechtigt auch ohne besondere Kennzeichnung nicht zu der Annahme,
dass solche Namen im Sinne der Warenzeichen- und Markenschutz-Gesetzgebung als frei
zu betrachten wären und daher von jedermann benutzt werden dürften.
Die Informationen in diesem Werk wurden mit Sorgfalt erarbeitet. Dennoch können
Fehler nicht vollständig ausgeschlossen werden, und die Diplomarbeiten Agentur, die
Autoren oder Übersetzer übernehmen keine juristische Verantwortung oder irgendeine
Haftung für evtl. verbliebene fehlerhafte Angaben und deren Folgen.
Diplomica GmbH
http://www.diplom.de, Hamburg 2006
Printed in Germany

Table of Contents
Chapter 1: Introduction ... 2
Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization and Instability ... 9
2.1. A Review of Relevant Economic and Conflict Literature ... 10
2.2. A Panorama of the State Structure in Developing Countries... 11
2.3. The Long-Term Consequences of Economic Liberalization ... 14
2.4. The Distributional Consequences in the Short-Run ... 16
2.4.1. A Market Perspective ... 16
2.4.2. An Institutional Perspective ... 17
2.4.3. Conflicting Interests ... 20
2.5. A Comprehensive Argument and its Exemplary Application with the Rubinstein
Model... 21
2.6. Intervening Factors... 26
Chapter 3: Methodology... 33
3.1. Data and Operationalization... 33
3.2. Discussion of Statistical Models ... 39
Chapter 4: Quantitative Analyses... 44
4.1. Descriptive Statistics ... 44
4.2. Regression Analyses... 50
4.2.1. The Full Sample ... 51
4.2.2. The African Sub-Sample ... 57
4.3. Discussion ... 64
4.4. Regression Diagnostics ... 68
Chapter 5: The Case of Guinea-Bissau ... 71
5.1. The Course of Events ... 71
5.2. Analyzing the Events... 76
Chapter 6: Conclusion ... 79
Appendix ... 81
A.1. Correlation Matrix for the Ordinary Logit Models ... 82
1.1. Full Sample... 82
1.2. African Sub-Sample ... 85
A.2. Correlations for Development, Urban Population and Secondary School Enrolment88
2

A.3. Likelihood Ratio Tests for Splines in the Full Sample... 88
A.4. Wald Tests performed after Regression for the Full Sample ... 88
A.5. Likelihood Ratio Tests for Splines in the African Sub-Sample ... 90
A.6. Wald Tests performed after Regression for the African Sub-Sample ... 91
A.7. Regression Diagnostic ... 93
7.1. ROC Curves for Ordinary Logit Models... 93
7.2. Leverage and Discrepancy ... 94
7.3. Scatterplots of Pearson Residuals against Predicted Probabilities... 96
References ... 99
List of Figures and Tables
Figure 1: Literature on Globalization... 4
Figure 2: Trade Flows and Trade Policy, 1973-1995... 5
Figure 3: Mean Trade Openness ... 45
Figure 4: Incidences of Internal Conflict ... 47
Table 1: Description of the Full Sample ... 38
Table 2: Description of the African Sub-Sample ... 38
Table 3: Comparative Mean Growth Rates... 44
Table 4: Internal Conflict and Trade Openness... 48
Table 5: Internal Conflict and the Opening Process... 49
Table 6: Expected Influences of the Independent Variables on Conflict... 51
Table 7: Regression Analyses for the Full Sample ... 52
Table 8: Regression Analyses for the Full Sample with Secondary School Enrolment ... 56
Table 9: Regression Analyses for the African Sub-Sample ... 58
Table 10: Regression Analyses for the African Sub-Sample with Secondary School
Enrolment ... 62
Table 11: Synopsis of the Results ... 66
Table 12: Regression Analyses Excluding Influential Cases... 69
3

Chapter 1:Introduction
Chapter 1: Introduction
Globalization is on everyone's lips. The German parliament was the first to set up a
commission of enquiry dealing with questions related to globalization which recently
published its final report (Deutscher Bundestag 2002). During the nineties globalization has
become one of the most disputed issues in the social sciences and a lively debate about its
possible detrimental or beneficial consequences is going on. In his article Guillén
summarizes the debates about the main fundamental questions and notes that the "most
bewildering feature of the literature [...] is [...] the remarkable diversity of authors that have
contributed to it (Guillén 2001: 240). Figure 1 shows the considerable increase in literature
on globalization.
Figure 1: Literature on Globalization
0
200
400
600
800
1000
1200
1980
1985
1990
1995
1998
Sociological Abstracts
Economic Literature
Politics & Int. Relations
Historical Abstracts
Anthropoligical Abstracts
Books in Print
Source: Author's presentation using data from Guillén 2001. Literature refers to articles or books with the
words "global" or "globalization" in the title, subject heading or abstract.
Whereas historians and even more so anthropologists have just recently begun to deal
with the topic, scholars of sociology, economy and international relations yet at the
beginning of the 1980s have been aware of this phenomena. Globalization has a myriad of
connotations (Guillén 2001). In my paper I will merely deal with the economic dimension of
this process and leave cultural concerns like the emergence of cultural homogeneity, with
which sociologists tend to deal, aside.
4

Chapter 1:Introduction
The increase in cross-border economic exchanges shown in Figure 2 has been
facilitated through the reduction of transport costs, communication costs and the consequent
abolition of barriers of political as well as economic kind (Frieden and Rogowski 1997). It
becomes obvious that the crucial development in reduction of trade tariffs took place at the
end of the 1980s, which is the time when most structural adjustment programs led by the
international financial institutions - the Bretton Woods Institutions - were either
implemented or began to take effect.
Figure 2: Trade Flows and Trade Policy, 1973-1995
5
ource: Garrett, G. (2000). The Causes of Globalization. http://www.yale.edu/leitner/pdf/2000-02.pdf.
mong scholars of the economy in general there exists the consensus that global economic
S
A
integration contributes to welfare enhancement through market allocations that are assumed
to be efficient (Rodrik 1994, Krugman/Obstfeld 2000). The majority of papers hereby
concentrate on explaining what causes the increasing economic liberalization, the feasibility
of these reforms, limiting the debate to the question of correct sequencing of the distinct
measures, or to the causes of either their success or failure (for instance, Frey and
Eichenberger 1994; Geddes 1994; Grindle, 2001; Rodrik 1994 and 2002; Stern 1991; World

Chapter 1:Introduction
Bank 1989; World Bank 2000). Although concerns that states may lack the adequate
structures to deal with such a process exist as well (Rodrik 1997), the possibility that this
process might lead to domestic instability has been neglected so far.
Another phenomena puzzling scholars had been the increasing amount of armed
intrastate conflicts around the world which reached its peak in the early 1990s (Gleditsch et
al. 2002). After the end of the cold war, interstate war vanished more and more from the
popular research agendas and attention was directed towards internal conflicts. Whereas
previously scholars concentrated their explanations for internal wars mainly on deprivation
theory, thereby modeling social cleavages, or on political structures offering the opportunity
for mobilizing rebellious upheavals, economic aspects gained in interest as well, but
economic liberalization per se was not considered as a causal factor.
I will therefore bridge the gap between these research agendas and draw the attention
to the question of whether economic liberalization is likely to fan the flames of domestic
violent conflict. Trade is seen as mutually beneficial for the trading partners and fosters
export-led growth. Theoretically, free trade could lessen the likelihood of violent conflict in
two different ways. On the one hand, foreign trade enhances the welfare of society, thus
reducing economic discontents of the population. On the other hand Kant (1795 [1987])
claimed that trading democracies do not engage in war with each other, as war interrupts
trade flows, thus being too costly for both the state and its citizens. But these benefits will
only take effect in the long-term, leaving a risk of instability in the short run. After an
economic reform has been introduced, distributional effects will have a major impact on
society, causing winners and losers. This situation is conflict prone if the winners are not
able or willing to compensate the losers for their economic losses.
Yet in 1989 Rogowski presented a model to explain cleavages arising in society
through the implementation of economic liberalization, which have the potential to increase
domestic instability. For his explanation he draws on the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem that
states that trade will benefit the abundant factor in each nation and harm the scarce factor as
trade in goods compensates for national scarcities in factor supplies. But Rogowski ignores
institutional arrangements and stays within his market perspectives.
So in addition to the examination of the causal relationship between economic
liberalization and domestic conflict, I will also bridge the micro-macro gap. I assume that
institutional arrangements such as the protection of property rights, a competitive electoral
system, the rule of law, and representative political institutions are important for both the
6

Chapter 1:Introduction
sustainability of economic reform and the prevention of violent conflict. Dealing with
developing countries this aspect is even of special importance as the majority of those
countries lacks such institutions completely or are inconsistent political systems which can
be easily controlled by elite groups having personal interests at stake. A weak institutional
state structure offers rent seeking groups with organizational advantages the possibility for
exploiting the wealth of a nation and distribute it among supporters. A reform like economic
liberalization is likely to alter and change institutions, threatening such a system. I therefore
will present various possible scenarios for the interaction between economic liberalization
and domestic conflict.
Obviously, the struggles about the distribution of the costs and the limitation of the
access to the country's wealth made possible by the lack of regulatory institutions will be
characterized by bargain processes between the contending groups. The Rubinstein Model
(Rubinstein 1982) is helpful to model such non-cooperative bargaining processes and to give
a better idea of the interaction of violence and bargaining. As the focus of my paper lies on
the statistical analysis, I will only give a succinct description of the Rubinstein bargaining
model. This model would be appropriate to investigate such bargaining processes in detail
when concentrating on a thorough case study.
Testing statistically the causal mechanism between economic liberalization and
domestic conflict and intervening factors, I will engage in comparative work in a dual sense:
I will move across different levels of analysis and compare the three statistical models
ordinary logit, random effects logit and general estimating equation. I will start with a
sample comprising 90 developing countries covering the period of 1978 to 1998 and will
focus afterwards on African countries for the same time period. The African continent has
puzzled scholars for its outlier position as it displays considerably poor growth and recently
a relatively high conflict incidence. I will also include intervening factors of political,
sociological, and economical kinds such as, for instance, regime type, ethno-linguistic
fractionalization, growth and development, and population size. Presenting the case of
Guinea-Bissau will finally give me the possibility to examine the propositions derived from
Rubinstein Model.
Although some of the control variables do not perform as predicted and even do so in
a statistically significant way, the outcomes of the statistical analyses in general do support
my question of interest and do show the expected relationship between economic
liberalization and domestic conflict. Furthermore, the results do not differ essentially across
7

Chapter 1:Introduction
the models presented and the relative effects maintain stable, which strengthens the
confidence in the postulated relationship.
My paper is organized as follows: in the next chapter I will lay the theoretical basis
and explain how economic liberalization may lead to domestic instability and violent
conflict. Moreover I will present a succinct Rubinstein Model, discuss the intervening factors
and derive testable hypothesis. Chapter 3 is dedicated to the methodology. After having
presented and described the data set I will specify the three statistical models. In Chapter 4,
first of all the data set will be expounded in terms of descriptive statistics which gives me the
opportunity to give full particulars about the outlier position of the African continent.
Afterwards, the regression analyses will be carried out separately for the full sample and the
sub-sample of African countries and the results discussed. The regression diagnostics
conclude the statistical analyses. Chapter 5 will incorporate the propositions derived from
the Rubinstein Model and highlight them through the case of Guinea-Bissau. The last
chapter gives the conclusion of my investigation.
8

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
and Instability
The purpose of this paper is to establish a causal relationship between economic
liberalization
1
and instability
2
. Thus far, the literature on trade openness focused on the
reasons why an increasing number of states liberalize or liberalized their economies, the
feasibility of those reforms and their subsequent economic effects. Those scholars dealing
with internal conflict mainly concentrated on deprivation theory, thereby modeling social
cleavages, or on political structures offering the opportunity for mobilizing rebellious
upheavals. Recently, economic aspects have also been taken into account, but generally as
resources providing lootable income to rebels.
This paper intends to bridge the gap between these research agendas. In this chapter,
I will outline the theoretical basis for the question of interest, namely whether the prevalence
of trade openness is causing conflict.
In the following sections, I will first
review the main strands of the existing literature
in the economic and the conflict research area. Then I will describe the prevailing state
structure in developing countries in terms of economic, political, and societal features, since
this is an important aspect of understanding the impact and consequences a trade reform
might have. Afterwards I will clarify briefly the long-term effects of economic liberalization.
The short-term consequences and their relation to conflict will be specified more precisely,
above all the connection between trade, conflict and institutions. Subsequently, I will present
a succinct bargaining model for domestic conflict and put forward some propositions that
will guide the short case study about Guinea-Bissau. Consequently, I present some factors
which intervene in the postulated association between trade openness and domestic conflict,
and thus have to be taken into account. While presenting the theoretical foundations, in this
chapter I will also derive my hypothesis that will be examined with the statistical tool of
regression analysis.
9
1
I do not discriminate between the terms economic liberalization and trade openness and use them
interchangeable. Both terms refer to a situation or process in which the necessary changes in institutions
guaranteeing free trade, like the abolition of tariffs, quotas or import/export restrictions, are being made. I thus
neglect movements of services and capital.
2
Instability refers to a situation threatening the political system. In the following I will use internal conflict,
domestic conflict and violence interchangeable.

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
2.1. A Review of Relevant Economic and Conflict Literature
In general, among international economic organizations and scholars of economic
theory, a consensus exists that global economic integration contributes to welfare
enhancement through market allocations that are assumed to be efficient (Rodrik 1994,
Krugman/Obstfeld 2000). Although it is equally widely accepted that trade policy is
redistributive in nature and that the gains and costs of trade liberalization may be very
unevenly distributed, thus causing winners and losers in society, little effort has been made
in the literature of international political economy to further investigate the possibility that
this distributional effect might be a source of violent domestic conflicts. Most papers
concentrate on explaining the phenomenon that an increasing number of developing
countries liberalized their economies during the last two decades, a trend which Rodrik
denominated as "the rush to free trade" (Rodrik 1994: 61). Likewise, when dealing with the
implementation of reform processes, questions discussed refer to the feasibility of these
reforms, limiting the debate to the question of correct sequencing of the distinct measures
(for instance, Frey and Eichenberger 1994; Stern 1991; World Bank 1989; World Bank
2000), or to the causes of either their success or failure (for instance Geddes 1994; Grindle,
2001; Rodrik 2002).
Two areas can be distinguished in conflict research: some scholars concentrate on
interstate conflicts, others focus on internal conflicts, mainly civil war. In the research area
of interstate war a vast literature exists on the liberal peace thesis, which Beck, Katz and
Tucker (1998) subdivide into a political and an economic element. The political component
deals with the proposition that democracies do not fight each other, or at least are less likely
to engage in military conflict with one another. The latter mentioned economic part, is
concerned with the statement that trade has a pacifying effect on the likelihood of interstate
conflict as trading partners do not engage in war with one another. Recently, Hegre et al.
(2001) applied this research agenda to the field of civil war, posing the question of whether
the observed increasing democratization during the last decade will lead to a democratic civil
peace.
But by and large, scholarship investigating the causes of civil war used to focus on
social cleavages, and used to work either in the tradition of the deprivation theory (Gurr
1970) or modeled violent conflict within the political opportunity framework (Tilly 1978). In
the former mentioned theory, the concept of relative deprivation plays an important role. The
10

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
degree of felt discrimination does not correspond with an objective discrimination, but
depends on a comparison of the actual situation with the expectation of an individual or
collective actor on the basis of a reference group. Habitually these discontents experienced
have economic sources. These studies frequently examine topics like nationalism, ideology,
ethnicity, or conflicts as a consequence of environmental degradation causing lateral
pressure (for instance, Fearon and Laitin 2000; Laitin 1995; Ron 2001; Homer-Dixon 1999).
This is believed to lead to grievance-motivated civil wars and people engage in violence in
order to seek justice. The latter mentioned, also rather traditional framework treats political
structures and processes as determinants of political violence. Structures are more likely to
change over time, thus providing opportunities to mobilize rebels and oppose state policies
(Tarrow 1989). In this approach, grievances are believed to stay constant and do not play a
significant role.
On the other hand, it is possible to witness an increasing number of investigations in
the research agenda of "The political economy of civil war" linking the causes of civil war to
more selfish behavior. Rebels pursue the aim of making the most of the opportunity and
organize violence to extract personal rents. By emphasizing the importance of economic
factors in civil wars, these studies turn the attention to the argument that greed instead of
grievance is the motive behind violence (for instance, Addison et al. 2001; Berdal and
Malone 2000; Collier and Hoeffler 2001). Although these studies consider economic aspects
like primary commodity dependence, trade liberalization policy per se is not treated
explicitly as having an impact on society that possibly leads to conflict and violence.
2.2. A Panorama of the State Structure in Developing Countries
The aim of this section is not to explain why governments in the developing countries
adopted the policy choices that led to the economic environment we are faced with today,
but to offer a succinct description of the prevailing structures that any reform strategy will
have to cope with when implementing economic liberalization. Some of these features fit
more for Sub-Saharan African countries than for Asian or Latin American ones, but the
general picture is the same.
The strategy that developing countries adopted for industrialization after having
gained independence was to build up import substituting industries (hereinafter ISI). When
doing so, they generally neglected some fundamental points that proponents of this measure
11

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
emphasize (Lofchie 1994). Instead of choosing a small number of industries that would use
local inputs, the number and range of these firms were immense and they often relied on
imported raw materials. Moreover, these enterprises were predominantly state-owned
resulting in deficit budgets at the national level at the end of the 1970s when the failure of
this strategy became evident.
Closely related to the promotion of ISI is the topic of protectionism. Protection
implies the use of tariffs, quantitative restrictions, and import licenses, which have the effect
of a tax on imports. All these measures raise the price of the importable good for consumers.
They aim at protecting the incomes of the import sector from competition and imply a
welfare loss for society as a whole. The majority of developing countries adopted a mix of
trade limitations which could be used quite arbitrarily, thus giving the power of personal
enrichment to the bureaucratic elites responsible for the allocation of, for instance, licenses
or contingents. Furthermore, tariffs and related measures are important to the government for
fiscal and budgeting reasons. In general, the tax capacity in developing countries is very
weak and states depend heavily on these sources of revenue to perform their tasks.
3
By
distorting the macro-economy the narrow governing elites generate short-term benefits
(Humphreys and Bates 2002). So in addition to the fiscal problem involved, the abolition of
such a system will also encounter resistance from those who benefited from it. The most
cited argument for protection, the reference to infant industries, implies just temporary
protection. But if these measures are not tied to conditions for the benefiting enterprises, in
the face of the problems mentioned, this argument is not easy to maintain.
Two more features stem from pursuing an ISI strategy. On the one hand, fixed
exchange rates, that led to overvaluation of currencies. The effect of this measure is the same
as subsidizing the ISI, as the imports of the required raw materials are cheapened. On the
other hand, industrial development was financed with earnings from the export-oriented
agriculture, a sector controlled by a state monopsony (i.e. a lot of suppliers face only one
buyer). Via marketing boards, taxes were imposed on producers, which on the one hand
served as government revenue and on the other hand provided cheap food for the urban
population. These two measures created a heavy anti-export bias.
In summary, this manner of implementing ISI had two consequences: Firstly, it led to
profound problems in the balance of payment and subsequently to a deep crisis in the 1980s
(Rodrik 1996). Secondly, it favored wage-earning groups and gave rise to a special structure
12
3
For instance, in 1986 Argentina 13.31% of total government revenue, and in Ghana 40.9% came from these
tariffs (Markusen 1995).

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
of political economy in the developing societies that proved to be self-enforcing and very
persistent (Lofchie 1994).
Krueger (1974) refers to this as a "rent-seeking society". The underlying idea is, that
"when a society imposes a limitation on trade, as in the form of quantitative restrictions on
imports, it is creating artificial scarcity. The opportunity to ameliorate that scarcity, as in the
form of an import license, is a valuable commodity." (Lofchie 1994: 174). These artificially
generated benefits have the form of rents and are created when the state restricts market
processes. The resulting activity of rent-seeking is unproductive for the society as a whole
and involves economic and welfare losses, costs that are also denominated as "deadweight
losses". This activity does not increase the value or the quantity of goods or service, but only
engages in the fight for privileges, such as licenses, and can be legal (e.g. lobbying) or illegal
(e.g. bribery). In the environment described above - high government engagement in the
economy - the illegal variant is dominant.
Moreover, rent-seeking prevails in countries with a large public sector, an element
which is quite characteristic for developing countries (Hutchcroft 1997).
4
Inside the public
sector, corruption is the order of the day. In some countries, this situation is aggravated by
clientelism and neopatrimonial structures, sometimes along ethnic lines. This system of
loyalty and dependence is a form of social organization and serves to maintain the power and
to secure the political survival of the president, the dictator or the ruling clique (Bratton and
Van de Walle 1994). The incumbent(s) distribute(s) jobs to loyal followers and confidents,
for which state-owned enterprises and the bureaucracy are welcomed instruments, and gives
these privileged supporters access to public resources. This leads to inefficiencies, as job
candidates are not chosen for their abilities and capabilities, but for reasons of ethnic ties or
kinship ties. Additionally, very often this system redistributes services, like education, within
and among these groups, which creates solidarity links between them (Azam 2001a).
The last characteristic of developing countries is the so-called urban-land bias, which
simply describes the fact that the most potent and demanding groups are to be found in the
major cities. The ISI strategy gave rise to this development which gets reinforced by it
(Lofchie 1994). Urban-land bias and the rent-seeking activities of political and bureaucratic
elites explain the persistence of economic policy. Remember that this policy, by a variety of
measures, favored wage-earning groups, which will be found in urban agglomerations.
13
4
Geddes (1994: 204) mentions that " in Senegal, 45.6 % of those employed outside the agriculture were
employed by the public sector; in Zambia, the figure was 81% in 1980; in Argentina, fairly typical for Latin
America, 22.7% in 1981."

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
Normally, the government is highly centralized and in contrast to the rural population, which
on average is dispersed and far off from the decision-making center, the urban population is
able to influence policy choices through informal relationships. If the leaders of urban
interest fail in their "quiet lobbying" (Lofchie 1994), they can threaten the incumbent(s) with
mass protest, strikes or more violent forms of expressing disapproval. So the economic
liberalization implies a policy that may not be politically desirable.
This short depiction gives an idea of how economic liberalization in developing
countries and conflict and violence may interact. Now I will go on to give details on the
consequences this reform may have and will connect these findings to the probability of
violent conflict.
2.3. The Long-term Consequences of Economic Liberalization
In general, trade is seen as a positive sum game, which is mutually beneficial for the trading
partners and increases growth rates for the domestic economy. The basic assumption is that
the best products and the best production methods will catch on. Free price fixing through
supply and demand will lead to the optimal balance between producer and consumer
interests. Countries exploit their comparative advantages in free trade, thus being enabled to
produce and consume more goods than without trade through increasing specialization.
Comparative advantages together with trade are believed to enhance the welfare of the
nations. Dynamic gains from trade, like the acquisition of new knowledge or changes in
institutions for instance, have even stronger long-term benefits and effects than static gains
which are inherent in the theory of comparative advantages (Thirlwall 2003).
This export-led growth has been subject of various studies. Sachs and Warner (1995)
find that open countries grow faster after having liberalized their economy and are also able
to more easily prevent crisis of balance of payment. Harrison (1995) uses different measures
of economic liberalization and finds a general positive association between growth and
openness. And Yusuf and Stiglitz (2001: 229) summarize in their review of present and
coming development issues that "...more open economies showed greater resilience in the
face of shocks, attracted larger flows of FDI, enhanced their growth rates through the link
between exports and domestic investment, and realized technological progress through
export competition, as well as increased access to more technologically sophisticated
imports".
14

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
Theoretically, free trade could lessen the likelihood of violent conflict in two
different ways. On the one hand, foreign trade enhances the welfare of society, thus reducing
influencing factors, which according to deprivation theory, above all through the concept of
relative deprivation outlined before (see section 2.1), could lead to instability. The Stolper-
Samuelson Theorem shows that the abundant factor in each country will gain from trade,
resulting in a higher demand for that factor. Since in developing countries this typically will
be the greatest part of society, namely unskilled work, it is assumed that the population as a
whole will be better off. But evidence about the distribution nature of free trade in terms of
the equality of income is not coherent. Whereas Eusufzai (1996) finds that enhanced income
per capita in open economies is overwhelmingly connected with an increasing income
inequality and worse Human Development Index rankings, Dollar and Kray (2000)
emphasize that growth benefits the poor as much as the rich and relative distribution,
measured with the Gini ratio, stays the same. Edwards (1997) comes to the same conclusion,
but also hints at measurement problems and at the importance of studies about trade
experience of specific countries. If foreign trade really contributes to an equal distribution of
income, it could greatly reduce the likelihood of conflict.
On the other hand, it is possible to rely on the argument of the liberal peace which
goes back to Kant (1795 [1987]). He claimed that democratic states that trade do not engage
in war with each other, as war interrupts trade flows, thus being too costly for both the state
and its citizens. In addition, trade strengthens liberal norms which disapprove violent
conflict. For interstate relations, this argument has been confirmed in myriad empirical
studies (for instance, Maoz and Russett 1993; Oneal and Russett 1997). The logic is
transferable from the interstate context to the topic of domestic conflicts. Likewise, domestic
instability hinders trade and reduces gains, even more, as both phenomena involve domestic
groups as actors. Collier (1999) estimates that GDP per capita declines at an annual rate of
2.2 percent during civil wars compared to the counterfactual. In his study on civil wars and
poverty, Elbadawi (1999) concludes that a higher incidence of civil war leads to lower
growth. So if the actors realize the losses and take them into account to their cost-benefit-
analysis, free trade can have a pacifying effect on domestic conflicts not only through its
institutional settings and norms, that normally accompany an economic liberalization.
Summarizing these arguments, it seems plausible that opened countries benefit from
foreign trade in the long run, showing higher levels of development, growth and stability. So
I expect a higher risk for conflict, also violent conflict, in the short run and will now outline
15

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
the reasons why.
2.4. The Distributional Consequences in the Short Run
2.4.1. A Market Perspective
In the short run, the distributional effects of liberalization will prevail. It is obvious that these
effects will not vaporize in the end, but the impact is most severe in the short-term. In the
long-term the process of economic liberalization is believed to be concluded and the positive
outcomes outweigh the costs via direct or indirect compensation of the losers and a general
adjustment to the new situation. In relation with Compensation Theory, Hicks (1939)
assumes a "balance of interests" in the long run. But it is undisputed that any policy altering
economic structures within a country has the potential to raise cleavages or to make existing
ones more salient.
Rogowski (1989) presents three general assumptions about the relation between
polity and economic changes. Firstly, potential winners of a reform (or change) will try to
accelerate it whereas potential losers will try to retard or stop it. Secondly, winners will have
the benefit of an increase in wealth that will enable them to gain political influence. Thirdly,
as the interest in the reform increases, the resultant pressure on political entrepreneurs will
lead them to attempt to overcome collective action problems. Rogowski draws on the
Stolper-Samuelson Theorem to explain cleavages in society that are caused by economic
liberalization and possibly lead to domestic instability. The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem
states that trade will benefit the abundant factor in each nation and harm the scarce factor as
trade in goods compensates for national scarcities in factor supplies.
Rogowski's model is based on the three factors land, capital, and labor. A country's
endowment of these factors is defined by the land-labor ratio, assuming that no single
country can be rich in both land and labor. An advanced economy is automatically denoted
as capital abundant. Depending on the kind of economy, Rogowski either predicts from his
political model combined with the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem an urban-rural conflict or a
class conflict accompanying economic liberalization in developing countries. In the first
case, land is the abundant factor which would benefit. Capital and labor, normally based in
an urban environment, are scarce and would seek protection. In the latter case, the economy
is endowed in labor, and capital and land are scarce, thus leading to a coalition of
landowners and capitalists supporting protectionism. Midford (1993) criticizes this
16

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
approach as incomplete as it cannot explain coalition building and cleavages in more
developed countries. However, he emphasizes that Rogowski's model is fruitful for
underdeveloped countries or for a historical perspective on today's advanced industrialized
economies.
5
Frieden (1991) offers a similar perspective as Rogowski, but draws his argument
from the Ricardo-Viner model, which implies cleavages along economic sectors and not
along factor endowments. The pressures to engage in or refrain from economic liberalization
will depend on the specificity and the relative competitiveness of the sector. Industries which
share the same characteristics are expected to cohere as industries in either lobbying for or
opposing changes in trade policies.
Frieden and Rogowski (1997) join their arguments, modeling the pressures for
change via exogenous alterations of relative prices like decrease in costs (for instance
transportation costs) or increase of rewards of such change. In addition to the two concepts
explained above, they introduce the perspective of economies of scale, where conflicts will
be expected between firms and industries experienced in international trade and those that
need to make adjustments in order to be competitive in the global market. For developing
countries, this view seems less suitable. However, all three approaches agree that economic
liberalization has the potential of leading to domestic conflict.
2.4.2. An Institutional Perspective
Regulatory institutions, for example those protecting property rights, are generally
considered to be important to foster economic development (for instance Aron 2000; Greif
1992; Knack and Keefer 1997; Rodrik 2000a; Rodrik 2000b, Rodrik, Subramanian and
Trebbi 2002). Africa's poor economic performance is attributed to the weak institutional
arrangements that dominate the continent, of which more later (see section 4.1.). Olson
(1996) maintains that because of by and large weak institutions in developing states these
countries have not yet taken advantage of their full growth potential. Also, institutions play a
major role in conflict prevention and resolution as they influence the way in which
contending groups deal with conflict (democratic institutions for instance Benson and Kugler
1998, and Gates et al. 2001; for social capital see Varshney 2001). Organizing conflict
suffers from a collective action problem. People will only join upheavals and the like if the
17
5
Rogowski himself addresses various possible objections to his model and hints at the possibility that it maybe
has only historical relevance.

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
gains outweigh the participation costs. Institutions can channel conflict and reduce such
gains noticeably, thus preventing violence. Easterly (2000) shows that high quality
institutions, e.g. rule of law, bureaucratic quality, can mitigate negative effects of ethnic
diversity and competition on growth, war, and genocides. So in general, scholars in
economic literature as well as conflict researchers agree that institutions are important
features of policy making, but it is difficult to identify the factors that may predispose a state
to develop the "right" institutions and overall, of what kind the right ones are.
6
A problem arises not only when attempting to put forward a definition of those
institutions, but also when trying to specify their concrete form ­ there is a wide range of
institutions that matter and a wide range of institutional possibilities. Roughly it is possible
to split them up into economic, political, and social institutions, where the former relates to
market and the latter two non-market institutions. In a decade of research, the attention has
been directed to tradable and enforceable property rights, rules preventing fraud, anti-
competitive behavior and moral hazard, electoral systems, the concept of social capital
7
including norms and values fostering trust and social cooperation, and the rule of law. Often
good institutions are just equated with the democratic political system.
Just as confusing as the variety of classifications is the high number of quantitative
measures of institutions.
8
A shortcoming of these measures is their limited time-span, often
covering only one decade, and their insufficient geographical coverage, especially the
paucity of data points for developing countries. Moreover, the evaluation of the quality of
institutions, e.g. their performance, a feature that seems of particular interest and logically
affects the policy outcomes most, often relies only on subjective rankings (Aron 2000).
Rodrik (2000) emphasizes that it is important to allow and accept institutional variety and
their local derivatives and argues that institutions develop best on the local level via
experimentation and incorporation of local knowledge.
This makes it plausible to investigate the effects of institutions in a case study
framework where it is possible to provide the necessary depth that their analysis requires.
Apart from the democracy variables included in my data, I will therefore refrain from
including them explicitly in my data analysis.
18
6
Some studies hint at participatory and decentralized political systems, for instance Rodrik (2000) and Grindle
(2001), which of course refers to coherent democracies as suitable political systems.
7
Hall and Jones (1999) use the term "social infrastructure" which describes nicely the idea of horizontal social
networks.
8
Aron (2000) lists 28 different measures that have been used during the last years only in the empirical growth
literature. She subdivides them into the five categories "Institutional quality measures", "Social capital
measures", "Social characteristics", "Political characteristics" and "Political instability".

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
But obviously, institutions matter, since regulatory measures like a trade reform, are
often the result of bargaining processes and therefore represent outcomes negotiated in
institutional arrangements. By and large, a reform process such as economic liberalization
consists of an interaction of need for reform, signaling for credibility, the costs of reform and
the impact of uncertainty on planning and implementation. Politicians, voters, and
bureaucrats interact through political institutions and have at stake different personal
interests with a different order of preference, such as staying in office, a certain public
policy, or career promotion. And of course, a reform such as economic liberalization is likely
to alter and change institutions and societal arrangements.
Moreover, institutions are important with regard to the aspect of compensation.
Rodrik (2000) stresses that institutions like the rule of law, representative political
institutions, free elections, social insurance systems, or institutionalized representation of
minorities offer incentives of cooperation as they constrain predatory behavior of the
winners and provide security to the losers. In this way, such institutions make a commitment
to compensation more credible and mitigate the impact of uncertainty.
But institutions, overall in developing countries are burdened with conflict proneness,
because "institutional arrangements of a society are often the outcome of strategic
distributive conflicts among different social groups, and inequality in the distribution of
power and resources can sometimes block the rearrangement of these institutions in ways
that would have been conducive to overall development" (Bardhan 2001: 284). Yet
Huntington (1968) noted that the process of modernization of political institutions is marked
by violence, a view which is perfectly adoptable to developing countries. And North (1990),
one of the first researchers providing an institutional framework, observed that institutions
do not serve the purpose of social efficiency, but rather the interests of those with the
bargaining power to set the rules of the game. Summarizing his view about the struggles of
the contending groups in connection with economic liberalization, Rogowski (1989: 20)
concludes his introductory chapter by stating that "[v]ictory or defeat depends, so far as I can
see, both on the relative size of the various groups and on those institutional and cultural
factors that this perspective [his model] so resolutely ignores."
In the following section I will briefly describe how conflict may arise. Whereas the
intention of the statistical analysis is to highlight the causal relationship between economic
liberalization and internal conflict, the case study on Guinea-Bissau will pay more attention
to the struggles between the opposing groups.
19

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
2.4.3. Conflicting Interests
As was seen before, the political economy of developing countries is based in principle on
import-substituting industries, which are often run by the state administration, and lead to the
creation of a rent-seeking society (see section 2.2). Additionally, the importance of
employment in the public sector has to be taken into account, since in Africa we find an
inflated civil service that is often entangled with neopatrimonial structures, kin groups,
ethnical ties and corruption. Public sector employment often plays an important role in
(re)distributing resources from the urban elite to rural regions and, as shown in section 2.2. is
used to secure support. This fact concerns directly the organizational capacity of the different
groups affected by economic liberalization and their respective influence on policy
outcomes.
Remember that the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem predicts that trade liberalization
tends to benefit the abundant factor of an economy. So potential losers have an
organizational advantage, as losses tend to be concentrated and apparent, while benefits are
diffuse and not obvious for an individual. Furthermore, because of the existing organization
costs, we expect that the bigger the affected group the less probable becomes its
organization, in this case in favor of liberalization (Olson 1965). In addition to this well-
known collective action problem, Geddes (1994) identifies the problem of what she calls
"external vs. internal constituencies". She falls back on the principal-agent problem to point
out that not all groups in society have the same access to information and can monitor their
representatives in the same way. This asymmetry implies, above all, a disadvantage for the
voters while the political and bureaucratic elite can transfer their informational advantage
into an influential advantage.
Thus economic liberalization not only shakes such an economy severely, but it also
endangers the stability of the entire political system. This is so since reform steps threaten
the loyalty system and the elite's beneficial positions. On the one hand, the rent seeking
system, on which the stability of the regime relies, is at risk through the abolition of licenses,
monopoles, and tariffs. On the other hand, privatization of state led firms and downsizing of
the public service sectors are core elements of adjustment and restructuring programs and
will cause extensive layoffs of state employees.
9
In this case, the well-organized elite, being
a privileged group, is likely to oppose such reform steps beforehand to maintain the status
quo. This is especially the case, where those loyal to the incumbent leaders staff the
20
9
Uganda reduced its staff from 320 000 in 1989 to around 148 000 in 1997. In Argentina, in 1989 the number
of employees reached 1.9 million. 180 000 employees changed from the public to the private sector through
privatisation between 1990 and 1992 (Schlavo-Campo et al. 1997).

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
bureaucracy (Geddes 1994) and impose high costs on the politicians, who are considered to
be rather support than welfare maximizers and are therefore likely to oppose change.
Another possibility for conflict arises after the reform has been implemented. Firstly,
as seen in Rogowski's model, the winners - the export-orientated industries - will receive an
increase in wealth. Politically the owners of those industries played a more secondary role
before the reform, which they will possibly try to change now that they have gained
economic importance. They therefore may challenge the incumbent(s). In a democracy this
would be feasible through elections. In a repressive regime this may lead to violent conflicts,
if the incumbent(s) is(are) not willing to change the political distribution of power through
further reforms. This highlights once more the importance of institutions. Secondly, it can be
assumed that the losers will organize protest against the measures implemented, if the
government does not abide by its promise of compensation.
10
This also might lead losers to
organize violence or join rebel groups in order to gain lootable income, which provides
short-term economic relief.
The theoretical arguments put forward so far can be summarized thus: I assume that opened
countries benefit from foreign trade in the long run, showing higher levels of development,
growth and stability. So I expect a higher risk for conflict, also violent one, in the short run.
(Core) Hypothesis 1: Economic liberalization reduces the likelihood for violence in the long
run, but increases it in the short run.
2.5. A Comprehensive Argument and its Exemplary Application with the
Rubinstein Model
Uniting what I have expounded so far, I can get to the heart of the outlined and present my
underlying argument: Economic liberalization will trigger conflict through the alteration of
the existing societal structure of (re)distributing urban rent-seeking groups, a structure that
constitutes a kind of social system that in modern states is provided by the state, if a
21
10
This apparently will include urban labour force as well, such as worker unions, as they will suffer from
adjustment measures in the short run. Moreover, Geddes (1994) observes that the working class failed to
monitor their representatives and thus were not able to make credible threats of punishment. This emphasizes
the points made about organizational capacities (due to different access to information, etc.) and the unequal
distribution of bargaining power that I will highlight in the Rubinstein Model.

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
substitution of this system is disregarded and an institutional vacuum created.
11
An economic
reform should not underestimate the difficulties that may arise when this horizontal state
legitimacy is to be replaced with a vertical one and inter-group cooperation problems
involved.
The incompleteness of the replacement of such structures is reflected by what Gates
et al. (2001) call institutional inconsistency. They argue that "political institutions cannot be
mixed" (Gates et al. 2001: 2) as the lack of a self-enforcing mechanism will lead to
instability. Neither is authority sufficiently diffuse nor highly concentrated to provide
stability. Thus, consistent democracies and consistent autocracies represent the most stable
systems. Remember the prevailing state structure in developing countries described in
section 2.2. States lacking institutions like the protection of property rights, the rule of law,
or institutions for the representation of minorities or that are inconsistent political systems,
can be easily controlled by elite groups having personal interests at stake. A weak
institutional state structure offers rent seeking groups with organizational advantages the
possibility for exploiting the wealth of a nation and distributing it among supporters.
My argument is not invalidated by the hint at the fast growing Asian Tigers, often
cited as an example of the economic benefit that liberalizing dictatorships may have.
Overland et al. (2000) emphasize that dictatorships pursue a "rapid-growth-at-all-costs"
strategy that reflects the incumbent's interest of stabilizing his power as this strategy enables
him to distribute rents to his supporters. This accords with a view expressed in McGuire and
Olson (1996) of the "encompassing interest" the stationary bandit has in the economic
performance of his subordinates. Furthermore Overland and her colleagues argue that
normally dictatorships grow at a faster rate than optimal, and they do so on the expansion of
social costs. This will lead to problems, echoed in the findings of Hegre et al. (2001) that the
median life for consistent autocracies is still less/lower than for consistent democracies.
Obviously,
the
struggles
arising from economic liberalization will be primarily
constrained by economic and institutional factors that will define the rules of the bargaining
game and influence the subsequent outcomes that are supposed to be solutions to the
problem of the distribution of the costs economic liberalization is imposing on the society.
Additionally, it is possible that the threat or the actual use of violence will be used as a
strategic instrument during the bargaining process.
22
11
Rodrik (2000: 2) argues that in Latin America economic "reforms have paid too little attention to
mechanisms of social insurance and safety nets."

Chapter 2: Theoretical Implications of Economic Liberalization
The Rubinstein Model (Rubinstein 1982) is helpful to model such non-cooperative
bargaining processes and to give a better idea of the interaction of violence and bargaining.
As the focus of my paper lies on the statistical analysis, I will only give a succinct
description of the Rubinstein bargaining model. This model would be appropriate to
investigate such bargaining processes in detail when concentrating on a thorough case study.
The basic idea is that two players - opposing groups or individuals - can distribute or
divide an exogenously given pie
12
among them, if they are able to agree upon the shares. The
players alternate offers, so that the first bargaining round consists in one offer made by
player 1 and the corresponding response possibilities of accepting the offer or refusing it by
player 2. If player 2 rejects the partition, she will place the offer in the consecutive round, if
she accepts it, the game will end. Furthermore, as real life would suggest, bargaining
imposes costs on the negotiation partners. Additional to fixed costs, time represents a major
problem to the players. Parting from the idea that "time is money", a discount factor
diminishes the value of the pie with every round of bargaining. As timeframe goes to
infinity, the pie converges to zero. This is so, because individuals assign a certain payoff
today a higher value as to a future payoff, for example, tomorrow. This means that the utility
is higher the bigger the share of the pie and the shorter the bargaining process (Holler and
Illing 2000).
For the bargaining situation of the players, various characteristics are important:
·
Firstly, the initial endowments of power and resources are of special interest as they
affect the discount factor. Negotiators with a low discount factor will be more impatient
and keen on ending the game.
·
Secondly, placing the offer first is an advantage as the second player must wait to the
second round if she rejects the proposal and bears the consequence of a discounted
counteroffer (Morrow 1994). This gives more power to player 1 who on her part is able
to offer less to player 2 than the latter would demand in the second round.
·
Thirdly, there may exist situations where the threat of rejection is not credible to the
offering part as the utility of rejection will be lower than the utility of acceptance (Holler
and Illing 2000).
·
Fourthly, as the fixed costs arise in each bargaining round, at some time a round is
reached where the payoff turns negative (Holler and Illing 2000).
13
23
12
It is amusing to note that political scientists prefer to divide pies whereas economists seem to have a
preference for cakes!
13
In our case, the opposing parties negotiate over costs, so obviously the pie has a negative value. But the
underlying idea becomes clear. Recall that a lot of trade reforms take place when the country yet is in a crisis.

Details

Seiten
Erscheinungsform
Originalausgabe
Jahr
2003
ISBN (eBook)
9783832493790
ISBN (Paperback)
9783838693798
Dateigröße
1 MB
Sprache
Englisch
Institution / Hochschule
Universität Konstanz – Politik- und Verwaltungswissenschaft
Note
1,3
Schlagworte
globalization civil africa heckscher-ohlin guinea-bissau
Zurück

Titel: Economic Liberalization and Domestic Instability
book preview page numper 1
book preview page numper 2
book preview page numper 3
book preview page numper 4
book preview page numper 5
book preview page numper 6
book preview page numper 7
book preview page numper 8
book preview page numper 9
book preview page numper 10
book preview page numper 11
book preview page numper 12
book preview page numper 13
book preview page numper 14
book preview page numper 15
book preview page numper 16
book preview page numper 17
book preview page numper 18
book preview page numper 19
book preview page numper 20
book preview page numper 21
book preview page numper 22
book preview page numper 23
109 Seiten
Cookie-Einstellungen